Journal of
Accounting and Taxation

  • Abbreviation: J. Account. Taxation
  • Language: English
  • ISSN: 2141-6664
  • DOI: 10.5897/JAT
  • Start Year: 2009
  • Published Articles: 209

Full Length Research Paper

Taxing the informal sector through presumptive taxes in Zimbabwe: An avenue for a broadened tax base, stifling of the informal sector activities or both

Favourate Y. Sebele Mpofu
  • Favourate Y. Sebele Mpofu
  • Department of Accounting, Faculty of Commerce, National University and Technology, Zimbabwe.
  • Google Scholar


  •  Received: 27 April 2021
  •  Accepted: 23 July 2021
  •  Published: 31 July 2021

 ABSTRACT

Domestic revenue generation occupies a central domain in most countries, leading to continuous mapping of strategies towards its enhancement. Taxation is a dependable and foreseeable avenue to generate revenue for governments to fulfil their key obligations of employment creation, economic growth and infrastructural development, poverty reduction and state security. Despite these plausible arguments, tax revenues are minimal and tax bases narrow in developing countries. Contemporary tax debates point out that informal sector represents a lucrative fountain of tax revenue for governments, yet opponents of taxing the sector suggest that taxation might cripple small firms. Zimbabwe introduced presumptive tax in 2005, further enforcing to expand the tax base by including the sector into the tax basket in 2011. Researchers have focused on tax evasion and non-tax compliance when studying this sector, this paper focuses on the stakeholders perceptions on the impact of informal sector taxation on revenue generation and growth. This study adopted a sequential exploratory mixed method approach, argued to be ideal for under-researched areas such as this one. Key findings were that the current one size fit all tax framework suffocates small firms. Governments have to strike a balance between revenue mobilisation and the sector’s key economic contributions, without crippling informal firms.

 

Key words: Informal sector, taxation, growth, stifling, revenue mobilisation.


 INTRODUCTION

In developing countries, the Informal Sector (IS) plays a central role, accounting for a projected share that is between 50-80% of GDP and a bigger share of employment between 60 to  80% and representing 90% of  new   jobs   (Bhorat   et  al.,  2017;  Dickerson,  2014). Zimbabwe’s informal sector is estimated to be the second largest in the world contributing 60.6% of GDP after Bolivia’s 62.3% contribution (Medina and Schneider, 2018). Mangwana (2016) expresses that more than 75% of the labour force is employed by Small to Medium Enterprises (SMEs) and the IS and this accounts for an estimated 5.7million people. From the statistics shown on the sector’s contribution to GDP, economic activity and employment, the exigency to bring this sector into the tax net in Zimbabwe is apparent. According to Joshi et al. (2013, 2014) and Rogan (2019), there seems to be a consensus amongst revenue authorities, governments, development organisations such as the World Bank, African Development Bank and the International Monetary Fund (IMF) that African governments would have to work industriously to bring the informal sector into the tax basket. Researchers concur that the IS occupies the most complex domain with regards to taxation, due to its characteristics such as the hidden nature, small scale, ease of tax evasion and mobility as well as diversity, yet they disagree on the impact of taxation on the viability of the sector’s activities (Joshi et al., 2014; Ligomeka, 2019; Maina, 2017; Munjeyi, 2017). The sector represents an understudied yet promising group of potential taxpayers. The size of the sector and its socio-economic implications as well as the exogenous inhibitions to feasible taxation policies have generated extraordinary academic and policy interest by both developed and developing country governments especially SSA country governments. Efforts by these governments endeavour to help augment the tax base, increase tax revenues, enhance economic development and reduce the reliance on donor funding if the full revenue potential of this sector is exploited.  Joshi et al. (2014) and Mbiliayi (2012) allude to the fact that revenue lost in SSA countries from not taxing the sector ranges between 35 to 55% of total revenues, implying that the losses could be even higher for Zimbabwe if the size of the sector and contribution to GDP are anything to go by. Developing countries introduced presumptive taxes to widen the tax base, bring the non-paying IS into the tax net and address equity consideration. These efforts have been argued to be unsuccessful and faced with considerable hindrances impeding effective taxation of this sector. Tax revenues from this sector are argued to be very inconsequential and worryingly low in comparison with the sector’s magnitude and contribution to GDP (Ligomeka 2019; Maina, 2017). Researchers such as Prichard (2009) and Masarirambi (2013) are quick to point out that a large chunk of this sector continues to slip through the noose of tax authorities, even as governments continue to grapple with the problem of how to manage this or even to efficiently and effectively collect tax revenues from the sector. However, while the subject of informal sector taxation has goaded considerable attention, this has not been without controversy.
 
Contention has surrounded whether informal sector taxation should indeed be a policy priority for these fiscally constrained developing countries in view of the potentially low revenue yields, high administrative costs as well as huge costs of collection (Joshi et al., 2013, 2014). Debate has also surrounded the benefits to be derived from taxing this sector versus the costs and challenges associated with such a move. Researchers have called for taxation of the IS to broaden the tax base, boost revenue generation to fund economic development (Joshi et al., 2014; Rogan, 2019), yet others have queried the logic of taxing the IS in view of its small scale nature, minimal and erratic incomes, lucid nature, heterogeneity and difficulties tracking players, aggressive nature of operators in the sector and low tax morale (Kundt, 2017; Meagher, 2018; Sebele-Mpofu, 2021). Opponents of IS taxation have further argued against taxing it, suggesting it is a means of subsistence and its taxation might be regressive and lead to the closure of small firms, crippling the very activities that are essential for poverty alleviation, employment creation and the provision of a livelihood for the disadvantaged. Political, economic and administrative constraints have been tabled as formidable challenges that make taxation of the IS unattractive and if at all a feasible option. Meagher (2018) questions whether any meaningful revenues can be mobilised from the sector, arguing that the current efforts to tax the sector represent an increase in the tax burden, as the IS in Africa is already paying multiple formal and informal taxes to local authorities. Pimhidzai and Fox (2011) argue that any increased efforts towards taxing the sector are likely to be regressive to the growth of small firms. This casts doubt on whether taxation of this sector is indeed a way to attain an expansive tax base. On the contrary, it could be crippling the existence and survival of the informal firms.  At the same time the tax gap, operational problems faced by governments due to huge budget deficits and the uneven distribution of the tax burden cannot be ignored (Dalu et al., 2013; Munjeyi et al., 2017; Masarirambi, 2013). The importance of raising tax revenues on a sustainable basis cannot be overemphasised. In view of this, it is essential for research to review and critically evaluate the implications of IS taxation through presumptive taxes on revenue mobilisation, economic growth as well the growth of small firms and to consider alternative strategies of taxing the IS. Is informal sector taxation an avenue for broadening the tax base, curtailing of IS activities and impeding growth of small firms or both?  In light of the arguments above, this question begs for answers. It still remains incomprehensible whether government can collect any meaningful tax revenue from the sector without suffocating these small firms or adversely incorporating them into the formal sector as questioned by Meagher and Lindell (2013). Machemedze et al. (2018) raise thought provoking questions with regards to presumptive taxes used to tax the IS, asking, “is this a fair system of tax, we are assuming government is making certain presumptions  about  the  earnings  of these operators, is this a good approach? What is the effect of the tax system on SMEs and the informal economy? Is the tax system designed to enhance SMEs growth? Does the system discourage growth of SMEs?” Submissions and conclusions remain inconclusive and paradoxical. Ojeka (2011) postulates that SMEs are bedrocks for employment generation, innovation and competition in developing economies which ultimately lead to poverty alleviation and national growth and contends that tax policy must not be an encumbrance to SME growth but foster voluntary compliance.
 
Zimbabwe is described by Ligomeka (2019) as one of the few countries that are slowly but increasingly taxing the IS. The country introduced presumptive taxes in 2005 and further enforced them in 2011 in terms of the Zimbabwe Income Tax Act, Chapter 23.06 (Government of Zimbabwe, 2005). Commenting on presumptive taxes, Mangwana (2016) alludes to the fact that the Zimbabwean government must balance the efforts to mobilise revenue from the sector and the sector’s other irrefutable contributions such as providing survival income, employment and value creation, being a driver and source of novel technological advancements, centre piece of economic growth and poverty alleviation. Zimbabwe therefore, becomes an ideal platform to evaluate IS taxation hence the question whether IS taxation in Zimbabwe is a widening of the tax base, stifling of informal firms or both? The objectives of the study are therefore, to explore the design of the informal sector taxation system in Zimbabwe as well as to evaluate stakeholder perceptions on the impact of IS tax administration on revenue generation and on the survival and growth of informal firms. Since this study is an exploratory study that assessed perceptions of various stakeholders, it also sought to design a conceptual framework to guide future researchers in evaluating the impact of taxation on growth of small firms. Fulfilment of these objectives would lead to contributions to the body of knowledge on IS taxation and to policy and practice with regards to IS taxation which is contemporary topic among developing counties governments, policymakers and revenue authorities. Revenue generation appears to be the most emphasised motive and studies have focused on the motives of and the need for IS taxation, without paying attention on the impact of such tax administration on other taxation motives such as governance, growth and wealth distribution. The focus on the evaluation and the outcomes of this appraisal of the IS tax framework would assist policymakers in improving IS tax policy. Maina (2014, 2017) points to a dearth in research that evaluates the current presumptive taxes’ appropriateness in mobilising tax revenues from the IS, provide justifications why they are performing below expectations and provide suggestions to ameliorate the handicaps.  Joshi et al.  (2014), suggests that, there is also a lacuna in literature that advances research in legal, regulatory and administrative reforms in informal sector taxation. Von Soest (2007) points to the insufficiency of studies concentrating on tax, its administration and impact in the African continent. Therefore, this research sought to contribute to the paucity in literature on IS taxation, especially its impact on the survival and growth of small firms. This paper evaluates perceptions on the impact of IS taxation in Zimbabwe in terms of revenue generation and survival and growth implications on these informal firms.


 LITERATURE REVIEW

Informal sector background
 
The informal sector is undeniably a consequential component of developing economies and has been a part of the Zimbabwean economy since time immemorial. It has however been suggested that the sector has grown exponentially in recent years (Sikwila et al., 2016).  Schneider et al. (2010) describe it as “all market based legal production of goods and services that are deliberately concealed from public authorities to avoid payment of income tax, value added tax and other taxes”. Pimhidzai and Fox (2011) proclaim that the contribution of the IS in providing employment and income opportunities is very fundamental in reducing the extent and intensity of poverty in developing countries especially Sub-Saharan Africa (SSA). IS taxation is a turbulent topic with connotations on taxation, economic development and growth that has generated strong discussions in recent years in developing countries. The paradox is how to tax the IS without crippling the sector and frustrating poverty alleviation efforts and the majority of people’s livelihoods especially in Zimbabwe where the economy is largely informal (Ayee, 2007; Moyi and Ronge, 2006).
 
Taxation in the informal sector
 
Resource mobilisation lies at the heart of economic development, if not the “blood life” of any economy, yet the “capability” to collect taxes continues to be a fundamental shortcoming of African nations (von Svoest, 2007). Fifty percent or more of potential tax revenue goes untapped in developing countries. In the wake of fiscal crises of the states in sub-Saharan Africa, designing tax systems that can provide incentives for growth, can ensure equity, stimulate economic growth as well as preserve the survival of firms and can increase revenue collection is central to state viability and effectiveness (Toye, 2000; Munjeyi, 2017; Munjeyi et al., 2017; Rogan, 2019).   Revenue   collection   is   said   to  be  negatively impeded by the existence of a large heterogeneous informal sector, corruption, low tax compliance and heightened tax evasion and feeble taxation administration in developing countries especially Sub-Saharan African countries (Joshi and Ayee, 2008; Ligomeka, 2019). The  features of the IS makes it hard to tax  the sector, as the actors are mostly unregistered, so mobile, not recorded in official statistics, small scale operators, deal mainly in cash transactions, unwilling to keep records and have little or no access to the formal markets.  The sector is usually made up of small scale traders, small scale manufacturing operations, garage owners, restaurants, small scale miners and repair workshops among others.  The current trend has leaned towards individual professionals such as lawyers, doctors, accountants, economists and engineers being players in this sector (Fajnzylber et al., 2009).
 
The statistics on the sector’s contribution points to an urgent need to tax the IS. Controversy arises as to whether to tax or not to tax the IS as proponents against such taxation have attributed the growth of the IS to rising tax burden and strict labour market regulations coupled with a declining tax morality and loyalty towards government. Contention also surrounds the enormity of the potential “tax gap”, which is the difference between tax potential and actual tax collected. Others allude to its vastness (Dube, 2014), yet others argue that erosion of the tax base is considerable, though not as huge as usually purported by governments (Pimhidzai and Fox, 2011). Amid the disputations, presumptive tax frameworks aimed at taxing the IS are slowly becoming an inescapable component of developing economies’ tax systems and Zimbabwe is no exception having introduced the tax framework in 2005.
 
Informal sector taxation in Zimbabwe background
 
The Zimbabwean system adopted presumptive tax rates depending on the industry (http://www.zimra.co.zw) in an attempt to magnify the tax base and increase revenues in 2005 as shown in Tables 2 and 3.  Hairdressing salons and cross-border traders were added in 2008, and cottage industry and bottle-store operators in 2009.
 
Should the IS be tax or not taxed?
 
Tax bases are narrow in SSA as they rely on few taxpayers. The large taxpayers, who make less than 1% of the potential taxpayers, contribute more than 70% or more of the total revenue whereas small and medium taxpayers contribute as little as between 0-25% (Gerxhani, 2004; Gordon and Li, 2009; Udoh, 2015). Taxation of the sector could also be a solution to reduce government-donor budget overreliance. Millin and Coetzee (2007) citing Xaba et al. (2002) suggest that formal employment and output growth have been stagnant in most African countries, while informal employment and its share of GDP have been steadily increasing. With the informal sector growing more rapidly than the formal sector, if not taxed then how would government increase revenue from a slowly dwindling formal sector especially in countries like Ghana, Kenya, Uganda, Nigeria and Zimbabwe? Various scholars focusing on tax policy regard IS taxation as challenging, hence less attention and interest is given to it. They argue that the mismatch between the formidable efforts required taxing the sector versus the paltry revenue realised as the major reason (Joshi and Ayee, 2008). Di John (2009) laments the paucity of literature that provides a clear guide on how to tax the IS, presumably because the sector is heterogeneous. Pimhidzai and Fox (2011) have questioned the logic of taxing the informal sector, querying whether such a move is local economic development or taking from the poor and stifling growth of small firms. Their argument is premised on the view that microenterprises in the informal sector are a major source of livelihoods in developing countries. The researchers argue that policy recommendations pushing for formalisation of the sector in order to increase government revenue through taxes could be misconceived.
 
A view shared by Rogan (2019) who argues that perhaps for large informal firms, formalisation might be beneficial but on the contrary for smaller firms it might have adverse effects. Using the case of Uganda Pimhidzai and Fox (2011) show that contrary to the widely held misconceptions that view the IS as tax evaders, the IS pays taxes- albeit not to central government but to local governments in the various fee payments. The single-minded focus on tax collection towards the IS, regardless of size or profitability ignores the role played by these enterprises in local economic development (Fox and Pimhidzai, 2011). Proponents for taxation of the sector (McKenzie and Sakho, 2010; Perry et al., 2007; Schneider and Enste, 2013; Torgler and Schneider, 2009), have pointed to potential benefits of increased revenue, growth and governance gains as resultant products of IS taxation.
 
Rutasitara (2014) questions whether informal sector taxation is a feasible exercise that can be sustainable in the future by these developing country cash strapped governments. Taxing the IS raises equity, efficiency and administrative issues (Dube, 2014). Taxes skew economic judgements as they create welfare loss over and above the revenues collections (Pimhidzai and Fox, 2011). It is therefore indisputable that the question whether IS taxation is indeed a route for widening the tax and thus should a policy priority still adjures for answers.
 
The question whether informal sector taxation increases revenue collections or destroys the growth of informal firms which is key to economic growth and sustainable development also remains unanswered. An evaluative review of the myriad factor by factor arguments aimed at unpacking this contentious subject is synthesised below.
 
Informal sector taxation and revenue mobilisation
 
Di John (2009) portends that domestic revenue mobilisation has not moved with the same strides with the rising public government expenditure. Therefore, there is greater need to take into account what governments should do or know better in order to raise revenue from the IS. Sharing the same view, Ebeke and Ehrhart (2012) assert that the ever ballooning public expenditure needs and budget deficits signal that revenue from the formal sector and foreign aid are not sufficient, making the IS a competing option for expanding domestic revenue. The argument is that the expansion of the non–tax paying IS undermines domestic revenue mobilisation and equity. Moyi and Ronge (2006) concur by pointing out that to enlarge the tax base and enhance equity, it is necessary to bring the IS into the tax net.
 
As underscored by Bhattacharya and Akbar (2014), steps towards expanding the tax base and enhancing revenue mobilisation should thoughtfully consider taxing the burgeoning IS. Benjamin and Mbaye (2012) assert that, despite the importance of the IS in African economies, it only contributes 3% of overall tax revenue collections.  The size and magnitude of the informal sector, implies the need to tax it if developing country governments are to remain afloat and be able to collect enough revenue to finance public expenditure (Munjeyi et al., 2017; Van den Boogaard et al., 2018). De Mel et al. (2013) and Bruhn and McKenzie (2014) adduce that it is unlikely that taxing the informal sector would bring in noteworthy revenues at least in the short and medium term. The researchers observe that formalisation and registering for tax can facilitate opportunities to get credit or funding, offer possibilities to engage with larger firms and government, reduce harassment by police and government officials. In addition, the steps can heighten chances to access to training and support programmes availed to the formal sector. These benefits in the long run will foster increased productivity and improved profits, ultimately resulting in a surge in tax revenues. Fox (2009) and Fox and Pimhidzai (2011) question the taxable capacity of the informal sector in developing country conditions. They point to the measly direct revenue possibilities from the IS. IS activities are characteristically constrained by their small scale operation and hence minimal levels of profits. Since tax revenues, are a product of profits, the lower the profits simply  implies diminished tax revenues.
 
Therefore direct revenue benefits of IS taxation are likely to be relatively modest or comparatively low (Joshi et al., 2014), and implications of equity prospectively adverse (Leoprick, 2009). From a distance, taxation of the IS appears to be a promising source of government revenue considering its size and growing share of GDP (Schneider, 2002; Schneider and Enste, 2013; Buehn and Schneider, 2012). However, in practice, the cost and benefit analysis tells a different story. Individual incomes within the sector are meagre, tax rates correspondingly low, while the costs of collection are substantial owing to the heterogeneity of the firms operating in this sector as well as the large number of individual firms and the difficulty in monitoring them (Ayee, 2007). Bird and Wallace (2003) state that the ease of tax evasion and hiding from other regulations by the IS makes tax collection from this sector on a sustainable basis a pressing task. Consequently, many tax experts are sceptical of whether any meaningful value can be derived from committing significant scarce resources in developing countries on IS taxation, given the inconsequential revenue yields, huge administrative costs and the questionable value of taxing low income individuals (Joshi et al, 2014; Kanbur and Keen, 2014; Keen, 2012). Fox and Pimhidzai (2011) observe that formalisation for tax purposes might not lead to higher revenue generation in some economies as the IS already pays some forms of tax anyway through licence fees and other local authority charges. They argue that the majority of enterprises will remain too small to pay central government taxes such as VAT, even if registered for taxes. 
 
In order for governments in developing countries to reap any meaningful enlarged revenues from this sector, they have to equally invest into it and nurture it. There is a great potential to grow the contribution of the informal sector to revenue mobilisation and economic growth if necessary institutional support is availed to them to foster their productive capacity (Bruhn and Loeprick, 2014; Bruhn and McKenzie, 2014). An enhanced tax base can only become a reality when governments start supporting the productive capabilities of IS activities through innovative formalisation activities that also address the growth constraints faced by the sector (Arosanyin et al., 2009; Gerxhani, 2004). It is argued that Governments of developing countries only want to tax this sector and not invest first in it in order to boost its productivity and profitability and then tax later.  Pimhidzai and Fox (2011) suggest that to address the dilemma of informal sector taxation, government policy should thus aim to raise revenues through local economic development rather than pursue the short term strategies that only focus on revenue collection through tax, risking the failure of small firms.
 
Informal sector taxation, poverty reduction and equity concerns
 
The contributions by Smith (1776) to economic theory on taxation are still regarded highly in economics and taxation. His propagation of the canons of taxation can be hardly exceeded in clarity and simplicity. The four canons of “Equity, Certainty, Convenience and Economy”, are still regarded as yardsticks of a good tax system.  IS taxation raises equity concerns.  Equity issues have to do with fairness. Horizontal equity is treating people on the same economic level equally for tax purposes and vertical equity is when those at different levels are treated differently (Dube, 2014). Players in the IS are said to have low incomes as well as low profits. Taxation of such firms is tantamount to disproportionately burdening the poor and is potentially regressive (Pimhidzai and Fox, 2011; Rogan, 2019). Fox (2009) argues that the single minded drive towards collecting more tax revenue from the sector could be counterproductive and at the same time worsen the vulnerability of the IS firms and individuals. Opportunities of poverty reduction would be lost in the process and the growth of small firms suppressed. Joshi et al. (2014) suggest that efforts to tax the IS also exacerbate the risk of coercive and corrupt behaviour by tax officials.  Arguments have been raised in favour of IS taxation, basing on the fact that if IS players are willing to pay bribes to tax officials and endure the inconvenience of harassment, why not pay taxes and operate freely (Pimhidzai and Fox, 2011; Prichard, 2009).
 
According to Pimhidzai and Fox (2011), SSA governments as well as the body of knowledge on economic development hold an “ambivalent” perspective towards the IS. The behaviour of the IS players and their role in economic development is often misunderstood, their actual and potential contribution to poverty reduction and provision of employment often overlooked (Biles, 2008; Evans et al., 2006; Fjeldstad et al., 2006; Fox and Pimhidzai, 2011). It is a fact that this sector is an indispensable part of people’s means of subsistence on the continent and a major driver for poverty reduction (Wafula Wanyama, 2013). Employment creation and poverty reduction are some of the major macro-economic objectives of government yet this contribution made by the sector to governments’ responsibilities are often ignored. From an equity point of view there have been suggestions for almost total exemption of the informal sector from paying direct taxes (Prichard, 2009). Pimhidzai and Fox (2011) contend that non- formal enterprises including those above the tax thresholds pay taxes at local level and their compliance is high. They are an important tax base, but for local governments. It is therefore unfair to view them as tax evaders. Their contribution should be acknowledged and  reciprocated in better institutional and tax policy environment if equity can be achieved.
 
With regards to equity also, taxation of this sector is said to be a step towards ensuring equity. According to Smith (1776), equity is defined as the situation when the subjects of every state contribute towards the support of government as nearly as possible in proportion to their respective abilities. That is in proportion to the revenue which they enjoy under the protection of the state. Basing on the statistics presented by Bhorat et al. (2017) who put the IS sector in African countries between the ranges of 20% for South Africa and above 50% of economic activity for countries such as Lesotho, Liberia, Zimbabwe, Tanzania and Zambia, not taxing such a significant chunk of the economy will equally violate the equity principles.  Despite that taxation of the IS would yield little revenue in the short to medium term, it will serve to bring the IS into the tax net in the long term, thus ensuring equity (Joshi et al, 2014; Terkper, 2003; Torgler and Schneider, 2009). The IS would be equally contributing (no matter however negligible the contributions might be) to government coffers in order to finance the public utilities, infrastructure and protection which enables the sector to function and make profits. Formal firms are financing the above through payment of taxes, therefore the troubling question would be, is there equity if the IS players become free riders?  The playing field is arguably not level as the firms in the formal sector would have their goods expensive because of the VAT tax fraction yet the informal firms will have their goods affordable less the same fraction.  The tax fraction would in turn make the formal goods less competitive hence tilting the scale towards the IS, giving the IS undue competitive advantage over the formal (Torgler, 2005; Rogan, 2019). As a result, the market share of registered operators would be lost due to pricing issues and the registered operator sales reduction would ultimately culminate in reduced VAT collections denying government the much needed revenue.
 
As observed by Benjamin and Mbaye (2012), systematic studies on the IS in Africa are lacking as some important dimensions are misapprehended and misread. According to these researchers these studies overlook the existence of “large informal firms” with sales and profits that rival those of formal firms yet these operate in ways that are similar to small informal firms. They “appear formal” in all dimensions but do not pay taxes. For these large firms for which formalisation is feasible, regulations and taxation should be systematically applied and enforced. For the smaller ones, improvements in support services and easing of burdensome regulations are in order (Benjamin and Mbaye, 2012; Maloney, 2004). Failure to tax the IS may be viewed by formal firms as unfair and as a breach of the canons of taxation. To exhibit the hallmarks of a sound tax system (equity, fairness and neutrality), taxation regimes must ensure compliance from both the formal and IS (Mpapale, 2014).  Tax burden should not be shifted to the formal sector only when the two sectors benefit from social infrastructure, service provision and related investments funded by taxes collected. Taxing formal employed individuals and not taxing the informally employed ones, creates inequalities and perpetuates tax injustice. Redistributive taxation may be seen as the best alternative to lower the inequality and provide tax justice as well as fairness. IS taxation is therefore not only a matter of revenue mobilisation but also tax justice.
 
Joshi et al. (2014) portend that formalisation for tax purposes might offer small firms a measure of predictability and protection. The researchers are quick to point out that the power inequities between the state and the IS may equally make the small firms vulnerable to unequal treatment and exploitation by state authorities as they will be now more visible, thus leading to their collapse.  Overall potential equity benefits of IS taxation can be pictured, but the pitfalls of such a move are visible too, especially the concerns of disrupting precarious livelihoods, increased vulnerability and stifling growth of small firms as previously argued by Pimhidzai and Fox (2011). Restrictive institutions impose barriers to formality that reduce growth rate of small firms and sometimes impose inequalities. Redistributive taxation lowers inequalities but blunts the incentives to accumulate capital, lowering growth (Davis, 2007). Examined through purely revenue and equity lens, justification for amplifying the base by taxing the IS rests to a greater degree on implicit and incidental connections such as tax compliance gains, growth and governance gains. These potential advantages remain only weakly studied and documented empirically as alluded to by Joshi et al (2014).
 
Informal sector taxation and growth exposition
 
Growth is viewed as the major target for businesses and also a fundamental yardstick for businesses and also a fundamental yardstick for business viability as well as a pivotal determinant of wealth creation, employment and economic development (Neneh and Vanzyl, 2014). The insinuations of a broadened tax base for growth of small firms are as prominent to the argument of IS taxation as the immediate revenue implications (Joshi et al., 2013, 2014).  Neneh and Vanzyl (2014) and Douglas (2013) explain growth from the entrepreneur’s angles as referring to increase in the sales, number of employees, profits, assets, firm value and general internal development. Penrose and Penrose (2009) define growth in the view of geographical expansion, diversification into new products and markets, acquisitions and  increase  in branches. Irrespective of how growth is defined, along with the growth arguments comes into play the need to cogitate about issues of employment creation and poverty reduction among lower income earners and the unemployed (Pimhidzai and Fox, 2011),long term economic development and the development of a larger tax base over time. The connections between these vital vectors are often misconstrued.  The major issue of consideration by tax experts is that, a rise in the tax rates or tax burden could hinder growth, threaten viability of the small firms and push people into poverty ultimately reducing the tax revenue even further. The costs may be far greater than the tax collections in the sector. The argument is instinctively compelling (Keen, 2012; Pimhidzai and Fox, 2011). Borrowing from the literature, the dualist view sees the IS as purely marginal, subsistence and a safety net for the poor (Sabot, 1973), arguing for an empowerment approach before any taxation can be considered (Fox, 2009). In support of the argument against taxing the IS, the notion that informality is actually driven by the burdensome regulations and bureaucracies of regulatory authorities takes centre stage. Informal firms are informal because they are trying to survive by cutting loose the suffocating burdens of formality (exiting) as proposed by the legalist/exit view. However, despite these cogent arguments, a growing body of research knowledge expostulates otherwise, proclaiming that, formalisation, which entails being captured into the tax net as the central component may bring about significant growth gains contrary to hindering growth.
 
While informality helps firms avoid certain costs, it also comes with a variety of costs for example, it precludes access to certain opportunities available to formal firms, including greater access to credit and financing.  Benefits such as increased opportunities to engage with large formal firms, access to government contracts, reduced harassment by government officials and municipal officers and access to training and other support programmes might be lost (Prichard, 2009). Formalisation alone will not yield any purposeful perquisites to attract the IS. Therefore developing country governments have to partner SME organisations through stakeholder consultations as well as show palpable benefits from formalisation.
 
Informal firms are often viewed as “parasites”. This school of thought considers informal firms as a threat to formal firms and as a stumbling block to economic growth. Impediments to growth are viewed from two angles:  firstly, the small scale nature of informal operations leads to inefficient and uneconomic production coupled with the incentive to remain in the “shadows” to avoid detection by public authorities (Ordóñez, 2014; Woodruff, 2013). As a result the inability to fund technological changes and  capital expenditure confines informal firms to an “informality low productivity trap” which adversely affect the overall productivity growth of a country (Kenyon and Kapaz, 2005). Low revenues from the IS may lead to over taxing the formal firms hence fuelling more informality and tax evasion.  La Porta and Shleifer (2014), table that the lower productivity has nothing to do with formality but has a lot to do with the proportionately small size, poor education levels, scarcity of economies of scale and shortage of avenues to export which characterise the IS. Secondly, tax evasion and regulatory non-compliance enjoyed by the informal firms allows them to impinge on the market share of their formal counterparts. The unfair competition that the formal firms are subjected to reduces their incentive to invest, expand and improve productivity. This line of thought might hold water for larger informal firms competing with comparable formal firms with like incomes and characteristics (Benjamin and Mbaye, 2012; Dube and Casale, 2016); otherwise, La Porta and Shleifer (2014) contradict the argument, adducing that informal firms are too inefficacious and non-identical to formal ones to constitute a possible challenge to the formal firms. Interestingly, Perry et al (2007) submit that informal firms are cognisant of their inhibitions with regards to scale, capital, skills and distribution channels; thus, they tend to ply sectors where they operate efficiently on a limited scale. The reasoning is why not find a means of taxing them without forcing them to formalise and risk asphyxiating them. There is need to support them rather than view them as harmful to the existence of formal firms.
 
Despite the fact that the IS plays an predominant role by significantly contributing to employment and output in developing countries, in addition to providing a livelihood for millions, there are mixed views on its impact on whether it enhances economic growth (Fourie, 2018). On the contrary, it may obstruct and slow economic growth. Proponents for this view propose the need for stronger fiscal and regulatory enforcements, while opponents to the view argue that firm level surveys do not find enough evidence to support the suffocating of economic growth logic (Fajnzylber et al., 2009; Maloney, 2004). Opponents to the argument suggest that the provision of low cost goods and services to the public can be reckoned as enhancing household savings which ultimately results in physical and human capital accumulations. Positive implications for growth may follow (Fajnzylber et al., 2009; Fox and Pimhidzai, 2011). Maybe results mask variations across countries and firms or they depend on the institutional and regulatory variations across nations.  This could be evident as argued by Munjeyi (2017) citing Gurtoo (2009) who attribute the divergent perspectives to developing and developed country context where the informal sector is adjudged differently. Developed countries   perceive   the   sector  as  a  “resource”  to  be harnessed, supported and nurtured through policy prescriptions in order to graduate into the formal sector. On the contrary for developing countries it is viewed as an evil to be extinguished yet it remains a fact that this sector contributes immensely to employment creation and poverty alleviation efforts (World Bank, 2011).
 
According to Mpapale (2014) and the IEA’s Budget Focus (2011), tax reforms are by no means strategies aimed at stifling growth or suffocating the very existence of informal firms, but reforms targeted at unlocking the ultimate potential of the sector, create new avenues for the poor to realise their potential and raise national competitiveness. These differing frames of reference open room for more debate especially on the causal relationship between formalisation, firm growth, profitability, taxation and firm survival. Another area of interest is the question, why is it that, despite these supposed benefits the informal sector is rapidly growing in developing countries and Zimbabwe in particular? Could it be because these costs and benefits vary across firms and across countries or is it a question of the legal, political and regulatory environments that are disparate across countries? Could it be the tax rates are too high and stifle the growth of small firms forcing them to operate informally to evade them?
 
Empirical findings on formalisation for tax purposes, taxation and growth
 
A variety of studies have explored the causal relationship between formalisation and growth with varying conclusions. Fajnzylber et al. (2009) provide evidence that in Mexico formalisation in the form of access to credit, training, tax payments and participation in business associations had positive effects on firm growth, survival and profits. De Mel et al. (2013) exhibit benefits that have to do largely with greater legitimacy and freedom of operation by informal firm owners in Sri Lanka as by-products of formalisation. The researchers found significant growth benefits for a small group of firms, while most firm incomes were largely unaffected. In Bolivia, McKenzie and Sakho (2010) conclude that formalisation, especially registration with tax authorities increase firm profitability, but only for medium enterprises.  In Uganda, Pimhidzai and Fox (2011) come to the conclusion that, any tax increases or additional taxes will hurt smaller firms and increase their risk of failure. Analogously, Ocheni and Gemade (2015) pronounce the negative impact of multiplicity of taxes on the survival of SMEs noting that the size of the firm also has an impact on its propensity to honour its tax obligations. The smaller the firm, the higher the risk of failure to pay taxes and the risk of failure. This would increase the vulnerability of households surviving through the IS (basically killing the goose that lays the egg). The increased risk of failure would see the same strategy aimed at growing small firms and increasing the prospects of tax revenues, resulting in their failure and reduced revenues respectively. The prominent argument coming out here is that growth benefits indeed exist but they are meagre for small firms. McCulloch and Grover (2010) point that in Indonesia, the impact of formalisation for tax purposes was heterogeneous across firms, with medium sized ones gaining remarkable profits increase and the small firms indeed citing exposure and pronounced harassment from tax officials. De Mel et al. (2009) argue that the benefits of formalisation though real are too sketchy to convince firms to formalise. They are not appreciable enough or exclusive enough to argue a case towards formalisation as concurred by Bruhn and McKenzie (2014). While studying how tax incentives influence SME growth in Rwanda, Twesige and Gasheja (2019), concluded that that there is a strong positive relationship between tax incentives and firm growth in SMEs. Notable from the different findings is that probably the impact of informal sector taxation on the growth of informal firms is heterogeneous across firm types and nations.
 
The inconsistencies in findings might be because preferences differ for small and larger informal firms. The latter might be operated by individuals who are still job hunting or just operating them to supplement employment income. These might not have a motivation for formalising and deem it an unnecessary costly exercise (Bruhn, 2013; Maloney, 2004). Fajnzylber et al. (2009) state that the dynamics of “inclusion or exclusion” might privilege other firms while disadvantaging some. Literature evidence has produced controversial and contradictory findings, while broader economic gains seem plausible, whether small firms are likely to benefit still remains haze. Equally uncertain is the best strategy to tax the informal sector firms without compromising their economic survival. Solutions to the challenges of IS taxation and its impact to economic growth will differ across nations and should be tailored to fit the local context (Heggstad et al., 2011). Conclusively, it is imperative to recognise that the actual benefits of improved profits, predictability, access to credit and training and support are likely to vary across firms and across countries. This is because power relations and political networks that link the state and individual firms dissimilar across nations and also vary in particular contexts.
 
Impact of IS on tax compliance
 
Compliance is perception based, linked to expectations and attitudes ordered differently by taxpayers. It depends on how taxpayers judge fairness, trust in political situations, governance, institutional quality and delivery of public services, together these influence tax morale (Martinez-Vazquez and Bird, 2014; Torgler and Schneider, 2009).  Despite the tax revenue potential of the IS being small, equity and growth benefits being questionable, it is highly possible that IS taxation might ensure high tax compliance overtime.  Paying little or no attention towards IS activities lowers tax morale and increases the risk of non- compliance in the formal firms (Ayee, 2007; Joshi and Ayee, 2008; Terkper, 2003; Joshi et al., 2014). More simply, it is a matter of establishing tax compliance among the firms in IS.  According to Joshi et al. (2014), the moment tax is viewed as a source of unfairness; this will lower the morale and reduce tax compliance among formal firms leading to a reduction in government revenues. Several researchers share this view and document this by providing evidence that tax morale is lower in countries with a large IS (Benjamin and Mbaye, 2012; De Paula and Scheinkman, 2011; Torgler and Schneider, 2009). Mutsapha et al. (2015), while studying tax compliance in Nigeria, concluded that fairness has an impact on tax compliance. Perry et al. (2007) provide extensive evidence that failure to tax the IS builds up a “pervasive culture of noncompliance” where large informal firms use “fixers” to manage their relationship with the state for a fee ensuring these firms do not pay taxes but remain camouflaged from tax authorities. In Latin America, evidence pointed to the fact that tax compliance is inversely related to the size of the IS (Perry et al., 2007). In Tanzania, Rutasitara (2014) found out that the reason why people work informally is because they want to avoid taxation and other regulatory costs. In West Africa, Benjamin and Mbaye (2012) document the presence of large firms which are “formal” in all dimensions (registered, have a fixed location and are able to access financing in the form of bank loans) but do not pay taxes. This has negative impacts on tax compliance. In Uganda, Pimhidzai and Fox (2011) found no evidence on whether the size or persistence of informal sector has an impact on tax compliance or drives tax evasion. These connections remain largely unexplored.
 
The impact of taxation on the survival and growth of small firms/informal firms
 
IS growth is curtailed by a myriad of challenges such as lack of technology, poor managerial skills, inadequate financial resources to fund expansion, capital constraints, low productivity and above all unfavourable taxation policies that are argued to compromise the growth of these small firms (Ocheni and Gemade, 2015). Alluding to  the  performance  of  presumptive  taxes in Zimbabwe, Mangwana (2016) expressed that “very few fiscal benefits have been received by the government of Zimbabwe from the current SMEs because many do not pay taxes. Those that pay taxes are not happy as they find ZIMRA to be a big boulder on their necks pushing them under water”.  The presumed nature of presumptive taxes or basing on assumed baseline results in a mismatch of the fixed presumptive tax amounts and incomes; hence this is seen as retrogressive and suffocating to small firms. Taxation has continually been cited as a major constraint to the survival and expansion of small businesses. High SMEs’ mortality rates have been attributed to tax matters, ranging from the huge tax burden to the multiplicity of taxes. Tax policy greatly impacts on the business fraternity. The more supportive and progressive the tax laws, the higher the opportunities of breeding stable and expanding businesses. This in turn steers economic growth. There is an interdependent relationship between business growth, survival and tax policy (Atawadi and Ojeka, 2012b; Ocheni and Gemade, 2015). Taxation is a vital tool for government to exploit for development, government funding, control the supply of money in the economy and resource distribution. On the one hand government seeks to broaden the tax base by incorporating the IS into the tax, yet on the other this same move increases the financial burden for the small firms.
 
According to Atawadi and Ojeka (2012b), the size and nature of small firms distinguish them from formal ones, therefore policy makers especially with regards to tax policy need to pay close attention to this distinction. These small firms are often viewed as minute and contributing very little in terms of both economic growth and tax revenues, but their great potential is overlooked. Tax policy should carefully consider a balance between the need for survival and the need to collect tax income, hence to tax and still “leave” adequate profits to foster business expansion. Charema (2014) submits that high levels of tax rates, penalties and the rigid licensing requirements were a huge stumbling block hindering SMEs growth in Zimbabwe. Tax policy should be aimed at minimising tax evasion and fostering compliance without leaving the taxpayer worse off (economy principle). These arguments call for the evaluation of the relationship between tax policy and the growth of small firms. Shahrodi (2010) suggests that for tax policy to be able to achieve its objective of maximising tax revenues without crippling the activities of small firms, it must be effective. The researcher expostulates that an efficient and effective tax system is one with appropriate and logical tax rates, easy to administer, has lower exemption amounts, is not overly burdensome to taxpayers and above all strengthens efforts to curb corruption and tax evasion.
 
According to Ocheni and Gemade (2015), developing countries should actually come up with favourable tax policies that aid the growth of small firms.  Tax policy must be enabling with provisions such as tax holidays and exemptions. The researchers give references to SME tax policies in China which they argue have been crafted to be favourable to SMEs, encouraging their financing by granting tax exemptions from business tax for financial corporations that provide guarantee for loans to SMEs. The tax policy in China also award tax deductions to the tune of 70% of the investment amount to market entities and venture capitalists that invest in high tech SMEs (Ocheni and Gemade, 2015).
 
A positive relationship between taxation and economic development has been alluded to (Twesige, Gasheja, and Barayendema, 2020), yet on the other hand, studies point to the negative relationship between payment of taxes and survival and growth of informal businesses (Evans, Hansford, Hasseldine, Lignier,  Smulders,  and Vaillancourt, 2014; Adebisi  and  Gbegi, 2013).  Those that point to a favourable relationship argue that as SMEs take advantage of tax incentives, it reduces their tax liability and in the process frees funds for expansion and growth (Feyitimi et al., 2016; Twesige and Gasheja, 2019). Problems brought by taxation for example complexity of tax laws, high rates of tax, multiple taxes and dearth in tax education and awareness have compounded the negative relationship (Ocheni and Gemade, 2015; Ojeka, 2011). Affirming this concern, Ocheni and Gemade discussing the impact of multiplicity of taxes in Nigeria describe multiple taxes as a “worm that eats deeply on the large chunk of revenues generated by SMEs for their growth and survival”. Multiplicity of taxes impedes the survival and growth of small businesses. Discussing the negative impact of taxes on SME growth, Machira (2007) advances that tax policy has unfavourable influence on the viability of the sector, as it reduces sales, capital, profits and employment levels. Atawadi and Ojeka (2012a) propose simplification of informal sector taxation frameworks, filing of returns and tax payment procedures in order to reduce compliance costs. They also recommend that developing countries must deal with multiple taxes on one income challenge, increase tax education and training for taxpayers to appreciate the incomes, deductions, exemptions and incentives they are eligible for if they register for tax purposes.
 
Omare and Erickson (2015) present the inability to purchase assets after committing the bulky of the resources to tax payments as a major hindrance to small business expansion, yet asset accumulation is an imperative measure firm growth and performance. Masato (2009) points out that an overly complicated tax system or “opaque administration” breeds undue burden on its taxpayers, especially informal firms and this distorts economic decisions  made  by these taxpayers. This has a distortionary impact on the development of these firms. Farzbod (2000) suggests that a poorly administered tax framework brings inefficiencies, increased collection costs, non-optimal allocation of resources and ultimately results in lower tax revenues. Reiterating the above concerns, Mungaya et al. (2012) opine that tax payments constitute a tax cash outflow, resulting in the reduction in the purchasing power of a company as more cash is channelled to the tax obligations instead of using it for business expansion efforts. Empirical evidence points to a negative relationship between payment of taxes, the costs of compliance and growth of small firms. Giving evidence of the negative impact of taxation, Tee et al. (2016) establish that taxation has an adverse impact on growth of SMEs and recommended the need for tax policy review and its alignment to the growth needs of SMEs. Resources committed to tax compliance could otherwise have been channelled to investment, reinvestment as well growth opportunities (Ocheni and Gemade, 2015; Tomlin, 2008). Observing a disproportionate burden as a result of tax compliance costs, Tomlin (2008) opines that the costs of complying with taxes for smaller firms are comparatively higher than those of larger formal firms. Ojeka (2011) further suggests a reduction in taxes and improved revenue authorities support services through tax education, training and awareness programs. Ocheni and Gemade (2015) posit the need for developing country governments to come with tax initiatives such as tax rebate for SMEs that locally acquire their inputs, add value to commodities and those that export. Ameyaw et al. (2016) submit that tax policy reforms should be aimed at bringing an alignment of the incomes made by SMEs to their tax obligations.
 
Holban (2007) interestingly views the negative impact of taxes on informal firms from the tax planning angle, bringing to light that informal firms may fail to leverage on tax planning advantages to avoid taxes or minimise their liability within the confines of the law due to lack of tax knowledge or professional expertise. Therefore when confronted by multiple taxes as well as high tax rates, the failure to exploit this key vector affects the growth and survival of small firms. Ocheni and Gemade (2015), exhibit a negative impact of taxation on the survival of SMEs, using ANOVA analysis and Ebere et al. (2016) affirm the negative impact of taxes on profitability, turnover and liquidity, ultimately affecting survival and growth. According to Atawadi and Ojeka (2012b), taxes impact on a business’ propensity to survive and enlarge its operations.  The researchers point to a negative correlation between tax and the small business’s propensity to grow and even augment its activities. Higher tax rates swallow funds earmarked for business growth and lack of investment funds results in curtailed business expansion. On the other hand lower taxes allow for higher retained earnings and working capital  resources to sustain a business’ going concern ability (Atawadi and Ojeka, 2012b). Affirming the negative impact of taxes, (Engelschalk, 2007; Engelschalk and Loeprick, 2016), notes that taxes reduced the rate at which the rate of growing for small firms as most businesses choose to forego their contemplated capital budgeting projects because after evaluation they find the possible after tax gain not worth the risk of undertaking the projects. Liu (2011) expresses that tax payments led to a reduction in working capital and deferring tax payments to reserve money to finance working capital results in accumulated tax debt and penalties that eventually makes it harder for small firms to survive leading closures or collapse (Nanthuru et al., 2018). To enhance the growth of small firms, tax policy has to be apt and not a hindrance to the growth of small firms.
 
In addition to the tax rates and penalties discussed above constituting significant outflows that affect the survival, profitability and growth of the business, compliance costs are another issue that cannot be ignored.  Due the complexity of most developing country systems the informal sector is often faced with huge compliance burdens. Compliance costs refer to expenditure incurred in adhering to government regulations and tax legislation. These include planning, costs for keeping accounting records, preparation of returns, filing of returns and paying of taxes. These compliance costs come in the form of monetary costs (payment to tax professional, accountants and experts who help with tax matters or even expenses on tax legislation material such as books and study guides) and time costs (time dedicated to record keeping, preparation of tax returns or dealing with tax professionals and tax authorities. They also include psychological costs such as anxiety, harassment by tax authorities and dealing with the demands for bribes (Sandford et al., 1989). These compliance costs, along with the fines and penalties as well as the potential risks of being inspected and extortionist demands of revenue authority officers and politicians often demotivated companies from wanting to grow and instead encourages them to hide from tax authorities as much as possible (Meagher, 2018; Sebele-Mpofu and Msipa, 2011). These costs in a way diminish competiveness of businesses and even the attractiveness of the country’s investment climate.


 RESEARCH METHODOLOGY

The study employed a pragmatic research philosophy and used a mixed method research (MMR) design that was dominant qualitative. The study adopted a sequential exploratory mixed method research design combining qualitative (literature review, document analysis and semi structured interviews) and quantitative research approaches (questionnaires). MMR designs are increasingly being articulated in tax research (Mckerchar, 2008), though researchers need to be careful of three things as advanced by Creswell (2016). These are:  establishing when the MMR design choice is appropriate, anticipating the challenges linked to MMR and to critically assess its appropriateness (weight, sequence and integration). Sequential exploratory MMR designs are  argued  to be suitable  for probing understudied research areas as in these areas it is difficult to identify what to measure, how to measure it, what variables or concepts to focus on or apply as well as what questions to ask (Creswell et al., 2009). In this case qualitative approach is employed in the first stage to inform the second stage quantitative part to gain a complete comprehension of the subject under study by combining the two approaches, together with integrating the results. Such is the case with IS taxation which is argued to be an under-researched phenomenon in developing countries and in Zimbabwe, with minimal available literature (Ligomeka, 2019; Maina 2014, 2017; Sebele-Mpofu, 2020). Creswell and Clark (2018) recommend the use of MMR for researching on understudied subject areas. The researchers state that the results of the initial qualitative first can be used to deduce variables and themes that can be further investigated on a much larger sample using questionnaires crafted from these results and enhanced by findings from literature review. MMR is also ideal when one wants to ensure generalisability of the study to a wider population and in circumstances where the phenomenon under study is complex. Therefore tapping into different constructs from different research approaches builds a more complementary picture as combining the two approaches permits the use of results from one approach or method to corroborate, supplement and give a context of the results (Creswell et al., 2009; Zohrabi, 2013). Taxation in general is a complex and sensitive phenomenon, with IS taxation even more complicated, hence the pragmatic philosophy through the application of the MMR approach was found to be more relevant to evaluate IS taxation. The MMR was such that it was first phase, qualitative and second phase quantitative as shown in Figure 1.
 
 
Semi structured interviews were held with 10 tax experts selected through purposive sampling using their tax expertise and experience (20 years or more) as the guiding criteria and these were identified through Institute of Certified Tax Accountants, Zimbabwe (ICTAZ) and 10 ZIMRA tax officers (from small claims office dealing with smaller taxpayers like the IS) as well 5 members of informal sector associations. The tax expert interviewees were made up of tax directors in accounting firms, tax consultants and advisers running their own consultants as well as members of tax departments in accounting firms. These were from Harare and Bulawayo. ZIMRA officers were selected from the small claims office that deals with taxation of small businesses and those from the audit section. These were sampled through snowballing from ZIMRA offices across Zimbabwe. The IS association members were selected from the transport associations, informal traders associations and cross-border traders associations in Bulawayo. The interviews sought to understand the IS taxation framework and how it impacts on tax base expansion, revenues mobilisation and growth. The interviews were carried out between 2019 and 2020. The three groups were targeted for the relevance to the study. The tax experts have information that is appropriate in evaluating IS taxation in relation to the main research question from their experience in interacting with both ZIMRA and the IS. The revenue officers on the other hand being tax administrators could help in assessing whether there is tax base expansion, its further destruction of the impediment of the growth and survival of small firms.  The informal association members on the other hand would be very vital in expressing  the  views  of  the  taxpayers  from  their lived experiences, thus practical appraising the IS tax system from what they have seen and experienced. The interviews were pivotal for the preliminary qualitative phase of the MMR adopted by the study. Interviews are allowed for deeper exploration and probing on issues thus giving a complete picture of a phenomenon (McKerchar, 2008). These interviews held were viewed as adequate as between 3-10 interviewees are argued to be good enough in qualitative research as suggested by Creswell (2014). The findings from the qualitative analysis were used to develop the questionnaire instrument.  The questionnaires were then distributed to a larger population with 73 target respondents (64 actual responded) drawn from the different categories of IS operators who are targeted for tax purposes as given in the Income Tax Act (ITA) and the ZIMRA extract in Table 1 and 2. Table 3 gives a snapshot of the questionnaire respondents and interviewees for the study. The respondents were drawn from the IS in Bulawayo. These were identified through referrals and with the help of members of the different ARE associations interviewed. This was because people are generally apprehensive of tax researchers so it would have been difficult to get the respondents to co-operate. The questionnaire respondents and interviewees’ educational qualifications are presented in Table 4. The qualifications were important for informed consent as well as for the reliability of findings.
 
Data validity, reliability and ethical considerations
 
The interview guides and questionnaires were given to a tax expert who was a Tax Director in an Accounting firm to assess the relevance of the instruments, point out areas of ambiguity to be addressed and to advise on the appropriateness of the questions. After effecting the expert’s suggestions the instruments were piloted on a small group of the target population and further refined.  The questionnaires refinement was also refined with reference to the tape recordings and transcribed interviews as well as NVIVO outputs. The methodological triangulation enhances research validity and credibility of findings (Zohrabi, 2013:259). Member check was also used to enhance the validity of findings. Interview transcripts were sent to some interviewees to confirm the discussions were properly transcribed and to add clarifications where they were misunderstood. In terms of ethical considerations, informed consent was sought and granted by all participants. Of importance to note is that all ZIMRA officers are bound by the oath of confidentiality, hence before undertaking the research the researcher sought authority and approval from ZIMRA, this was accordingly granted through a written approval letter. This approval letter was produced in arranging for interviews with the ZIMRA officers. The privacy and confidential of respondents was respected all identifying data coded and securely kept throughout the research process.
 
Accordingly the participants were made aware that the anticipated benefits of the research were to accrue to policy making and improvements that would have an impact on the IS, the government and economy at large.  Informed consent was then sought to tape record the interviews. All interviews granted the researcher permission to record the interviewees except for three ZIMRA officers who only granted consent to participate in the study without being tape-recorded. The researcher had to take notes during the interviews. In order to maintain anonymity of the respondents during data analysis and discussion, the participants were given code names. ZIMRA officers were coded ZIMRAOs, Informal Sector Association members were described as ISAMs and Tax Experts as TEXs. The questionnaires collected from the IS operators were analysed through SPSS.
 
 
 
Data analysis
 
Data analysis of the exploratory qualitative interviews was done through the use of NVIVO 12. The data was analysed through the use of themes and the transcripts were analysed until saturation was reached; this being the point where no new themes, codes and information emerged from the data (Fusch and Ness, 2015; Guest, Namey and Chen, 2020).  The deducing themes were used to design the questionnaire for the IS and the modelling of a conceptual framework. The codes generated from NVIVO were used to construct the statements that were used to elicit the responses such as ‘agree’ and ‘disagree’ on the questionnaire. The data collected through questionnaires was analysed through the use of SPSS. Data was presented in narrative form, word search queries (qualitative findings) and tables and graphs (quantitative results). The discussion of findings integrated both qualitative and quantitative results to enjoy the confirmatory, diversity and elaboration advantages of MMR.


 FINDINGS AND DISCUSSION

The study found out that Zimbabwe adopted a fixed presumptive tax system whereby various informal taxpayers were grouped into stratas and different quarterly fixed presumptive tax rates levied as shown in Table 1 and 2. It was also evident from participants that they considered that increasing government revenues through more tax collections as the major reason behind the implementation of the presumptive tax policy. Despite taxation being administered with several objectives such as to reduce market externalities, help government and citizens engage, stimulate economic growth and support the growth of firms, participants highlighted that these were not prioritised by government ( the majority of IS associations members and tax experts). The study found out that creating a conducive environment for the survival and growth of SMEs through inclusive tax policy at the same time compelling tax compliance was an arduous task facing many nations especially Zimbabwe. The informal sector was described by the majority of participants as a fountainhead for economic entrepreneurship, economic growth, modernisation, competition and employment creation hence the need to try and balance the revenue collection needs and the importance of this sector in the economy. The key findings were explicated in detail below.
 
Design of presumptive tax systems
 
It was established from literature and from the findings that Zimbabwe used a fixed presumptive tax system. The structure of the presumptive tax framework was presented in Table 1 and 2 in the literature review section.  According to the ZIMRA officers and Tax Experts, the tax rates were designed based on a study done in the early 2000s on the transport sector and that no further study was done. There was consensus among the IS associations members, ZIMRA officers and Tax Experts that the tax rates were not considering the actual profitability of these operators, thus being advantageous to those who were more profitable and unfair to those whose incomes could not sustain the tax rates.  This resonates with arguments by Machemedze et al. (2018) and Dube (2014) who called for the need to consider the ability to pay principle.
 
Perceptions on the impact of IS taxation on revenue generation, survival and growth of small firms
 
Low tax revenue contributions from the sector
 
The revenue mobilised from the sector in comparison to its magnitude in terms of economic activity and more than 60% of the GDP in Zimbabwe as suggested by Medina and Schneider (2018) was found to be relatively minimal.  According to Sebele-Mpofu and Msipa (2011), “If GDP contribution could be translated into revenue contribution, largely through tax compliance, the government would witness a significant revenue appreciation”. Information from the ZIMRA reports and Sebele-Mpofu and Msipa (2011) show that the sector’s contribution to total national tax revenues. ZIMRA officers explained the fact that the effort and costs associated with tracing players in the IS to tax them is not commensurate with the little revenues collected, hence they concentrate on the easy to tax formal sector which yields worthwhile tax  revenues. ZIMRAO1 argues that “the informal sector is difficult to capture in the tax net, they are too mobile and can easily hide from tax authorities, sometimes looking at the cost and a benefit assessment it is not sensible to commit our small resources and time chasing the elusive players”. This  appears  to  be  placing  the  burden  unfairly on the formal sector. TEX1 expressed a contradictory opinion on the low tax revenues pointing out that “the general feeling among tax officials is that the informal sector evades tax, but I don’t think this is wholly correct. The incomes in the sector are just very low to collect any substantial taxes”.  The two opinions may possibly explain the low tax revenue collections displayed in Table 5. The views also resonates with submissions by Cheeseman and Griffiths (2005) who advance that the scope for realising significant tax revenue increases by taxing the IS in the short term is less likely due to the high levels of poverty and the elusiveness of the IS.
 
An obvious irregularity in these Revenue Performance figures is the miniature share of “Other Taxes” (including presumptive tax) to the overall taxes. There is no proportion indicatively linked to presumptive tax in the presentations as extracted from ZIMRA reports, it is aggregated under other taxes. This demonstrates the fact that due to the inconsequential nature of the contribution, ZIMRA saw it fit to group it with other taxes. TEX2 asseverated that the fact that the presumptive taxes are lumped together with other taxes might possibly suggest the little attention that tax authorities attach to presumptive tax administration due to the likely high costs of collections for low tax revenues. Tax authorities tend to pay more attention to the large taxpayers, who are few, organised and easy to tax and yield substantial tax revenues. This was considered to be unfair on the formal sector and the few informal operators that are tax compliant lowered. TEX5 avowed that “this lack of prioritisation of the informal for tax purpose diminished tax morale among those who religiously pay their tax obligation. It is indeed seen as a source of unfairness and unequal treatment”. The minute tax revenues collected as displayed in Table 5 could be connected to the fact that the IS operators make low incomes or that the majority of them are not registered for tax purposes as shown in Figure 2.
 
Reasons for registering/not registering for tax purposes
 
The researcher further explored the reasons for registering and those for registering for tax who were registered and not registered respectively.  For those who were registered, the reasons offered include: access to government tenders and trading with large formal companies who ask for tax clearance certificates, access to financing and government tenders, fear of penalties and garnishes, fulfilling a moral obligation and religiosity. The reasons proffered by the registered informal operators were also echoed during the discussions by participants from the three interviewee groups as some of the benefits that ultimately contributed to the growth of informal firms. The benefits were noted as access to finance and government tenders as well as trading with big companies which leads to the growth of the turnover base and profits. The sentiments were mixed on these advantages. Very few firms were said to have been able access funding from the banks. According to TEX6 the general  feeling   shows   the  loss  of  confidence  on  the Zimbabwe bank sector by not only the IS but the formal one as well, due to policy inconsistencies, erratic currency and monetary policy changes. For those that were not registered, the reasons that were given were as follows: low incomes and small scale nature of the operations, excessive compliance burden and formal regulations, high tax rates and penalties, unhappiness with service delivery, complicated tax system as well as the high. The responses were presented in Table 6. High tax rates and penalties were the highly ranked, with all respondents agreeing to them as a rationale (92% strongly agreed and 8% agreed). 81% strongly concurred on burdensome formal regulations and poor service delivery. Results for other factors are as presented in Table 6. The prominence of the high tax rates and penalties  was  also  pointed  out  by  the  majority  of  tax experts and ISAMs during interviews. They linked the burdensome nature of tax to the high failure rates of informal businesses. Similarly literature alluded to this pervasive impact (Atawadi and Ojeka, 2012a; Ojeka, 2011, Ocheni and Gemade, 2015).
 
 
Relationship between business growth, survival and tax policy
 
There were mixed perception on the relationship between tax payment and growth and survival of small firms. Others pointed to a positive impact and the majority of participants referred to negative ramifications. Taxation of the IS was found to negatively affect the operations of informal firms. Overly onerous tax regimes abrade the profitability of IS firms, compounding the failure rates and essentially reducing tax yields. According to ISAM2 “most of our members own small and medium enterprise, the majority of these enterprises cannot afford to pay tax and survive. Several of them have collapsed due to taxes and garnishees from ZIMRA”. 80% of the tax expert participants argued that tax rates and tax policy have an undesirable impact on the growth of firms. The majority of IS association members suggested that tax is a cost that eats into profits so in most cases small firms are forced to either increase the costs of their products or reduce the number of employees in order to reserve cash flows to pay taxes. The former strategy makes IS business products pricey and less competitive reducing their sales, paralysing their survival and the after effects are reduced tax revenues. The view was also shared by TEX5 who expressed that “competition is very stiff in the IS and among SMEs because of ease of entry and exit in the market, so any increases in the prices to take care of the tax component will lead to a loss of customers”; the latter leads to loss of employment and compromising poverty alleviation efforts. Similar findings were tabled by Ojeka (2011) in Nigeria where he established a negative relationship between SMEs growth and Tax policy. The other 20% of tax experts (TEX 6 and 7), proclaimed that some of the informal firms were now able to tender for government contracts and trade with big companies due to the visibility brought about by tax registration and them holding valid tax clearances certificates which are often a pre-requisite.
 
They also suggested that those SME who registered for tax purposes could now access financing in the form of loans from the banks as their properly kept books of accounts could show the viability and performance of their businesses. ISA members on the contrary argued that the demand for collateral still made access to financing difficult even for taxpaying SMEs. The ISA members further expressed that even government support in the form of services, work spaces and funding was still inaccessible even for the tax compliant small firms. Similar concerns were expressed by Pimhidzai and Fox, 2011 in Uganda and Meagher (2018) in Nigeria. ZIMRAO 6, 8, 9 and 10 despite agreeing that tax rates are high in relation to incomes earned by the IS and that the fixed presumptive tax system was not ideal, they officers  contended that it was rather unfair to solely attribute the collapse of IS firms to tax and ZIMRA garnishees as there are other factors that have nothing to do with tax that can explain their high mortality rates such as poor accounting and risk management skills, high competition, economic challenges, misuse of funds and lack of capital among others. The discussion on the impact of taxes on the growth and survival of small firms crystallised itself in the word tree extract from NVIVO analysis as shown in Figure 3. From the top left of the word tree, verbatim extracts of conversations from the study participants show mixed perceptions on the impact  of IS taxation on the survival and growth of small informal businesses.  The visible conversations are: “it boosts the growth and the survival”, “positive attributes to growth and survival”, “might stifles the growth and survival”, “to suffocate the growth and survival”, “little earnings to use for survival and growth of small firms”. From the bottom left others apparent statements are: “not detrimental to the sector’s survival and growth of small businesses”, “positive and negative impact on the survival prospects of small businesses”, “and impact negatively on the survival and growth of small businesses” and “constructive impact on the survival aspects of the business”. The views on the unfavourable consequences of tax administration on the IS expressed in the discussions in the word tree are analogous to the advancements by Charema (2014) quoting the president of SMEs Chamber Daniel Chiremba who pointed out that “Presumptive taxes demanded by ZIMRA are too high for most of the growing SMEs. Almost 10 SMEs in Zvishavane alone have collapsed after failing to pay presumptive taxes and many more countrywide are collapsing”.
 
Negative impact on the survival and growth of small firms
 
High tax rates and tax laws were fingered as one of the major contributors of high SME mortality rates in Zimbabwe, in addition to lack of funding. The fixed presumptive tax rates were described by tax experts and 50% of ZIMRA officials as overburdening the IS. The fact that these rates are fixed does not take into consideration actual sales made (incomes), the cost incurred in making the income (allowable deductions) and ultimately the taxable income. Hence it becomes unfair to taxpayers who are assumed to have made income and hence a tax obligation arises. Failure to pay the taxes and accruing penalties has seen many small firms closing shop. The high tax rates are pointed to be inhibiting the growth of SMEs because as they focus on building cash flow reserves to meet tax obligations, they fail to reserve funds to finance business development, growth and survival. This signals an interrelationship between tax policy and capital investments. A relationship affirmed by Manyani et al. (2014) who used the transport sector in Bindura to evaluate the “Effectiveness of Presumptive and its impact on profitability of SMEs in Zimbabwe” and established a negative relationship. Presumptive tax was found to ambivalently affect the viability of SMEs. A similar view was expressed by SMEs Minister, Sithembiso Nyoni who laid the blame for decreased SMEs growth and increased failure rates on exorbitant taxes and penalties levied by ZIMRA. TC 2 expressed that “the unfavourable impact of taxes on the growth and continued survival of SMEs is worsened further by the liquidity crunch, high cost of money and short term lending costs due to the volatile economic environment, the inconsistent monetary and currency and exchange risk issues”. In spite of their acknowledgement of the negative ramifications of IS taxation on the growth and survival of small firms tax experts (TEX3, 6, 7 and 10) pointed to some advantages that could accrue to informal firms  that   are   properly   registered   as   SMEs   for tax purposes. TEX3 advanced that the ITA, Zimbabwe has a provision that the Commissioner General of Taxes may “on application of a taxpayer who qualifies as a small and medium enterprise” permit such a taxpayer to pay provisional income tax on a monthly basis, that is one month in advance”. Income tax refers to corporate tax in this context. This is as opposed to the general provision in respect of corporate tax that that requires taxpayers to tax provisional tax in advance quarterly in relation to the quarterly payments dates (QPDs)at instalments of 10, 25, 30 and 35% for the first to the last quarter in ascending dates. If taxpayers were to take advantages of this provision and accordingly apply and be granted reprieve, it can be good for capital working management. TEXs 6 and 7 tabled that registered SMEs were eligible for the Special Initial Allowance tax depreciation on assets (constructed immovable and purchased movable assets) at a rate of 50% on the first year of use, 25% on the second year and 25% on the third year. This allows the taxpayer to write off an eligible capital asset in three years as opposed to the 25% for four years awarded to big companies. TEX10 on the other hand, pointed out that the small scale miners’ payments for gold proceeds were subject to 3% mining royalty deduction, which is generally 2% lower than the general rate of 5% applicable to other enterprises. Some of these benefits for formalisation for tax purposes were highlighted by Tax Matrix (2019). Notwithstanding these notable advantages the IS associations members and some the ZIMRA officers and tax experts felt that formalisation requirements and tax payments suffocated informal firms. ISAM5 argued that “the IS firms do not have enough working capital not to even talk about purchasing any assets to enjoy the capital allowances. Sometimes the IS operators have no knowledge of these tax advantages or even how to claim them”. The negative influence of tax policy on firm growth, survival, performance and expansion was also highlighted by IS questionnaire respondents as presented in Figure 4.
 
 
Multiplicity of taxes unfavourably affecting informal operators
 
The multiplicity of taxes was raised as another source of controversy on the IS taxation and firm growth puzzle. Tax experts pointed out that the taxes faced by the IS were multiple on the same income for example presumptive tax, VAT withholding taxes on transactions that exceed $250 with a registered operator, the recently introduced 2% transaction tax and this is compounded by licences fees and other fees that they pay to the local authorities and their associations. ISAM2 expressed this fact by saying “the taxes faced by businesses in Zimbabwe are generally too many and for our members there is presumptive tax, the 2% intermediary monetary transaction  tax   (IMTT)   that    is   charged    on   money transfers, income tax on employment and VAT for those meeting the thresholds. The incomes made by our members cannot sustain these many taxes.” In light of all this IS taxation was found to be regressive to the growth of small firms, a view shared by Pimhidzai and Fox (2011) in Uganda. TEX5 asseverate that “the impact of the 2%IMTT is impacting badly not only on companies but on disposable incomes of individuals especially in an environment whether there are significant cash shortages as Zimbabwe. Assume you make a transfer of $500 000, the 2% IMTT is $10 000. That’s a lot of money for small firms”.  Despite acknowledging the multiple taxes badly affecting the performance of small firms and taking money for investment and expansion needs, other tax experts were quick to point out that for those small firms who managed to register for VAT, even voluntarily, they are able to claim VAT input tax and also avoid the 10% withholding tax on tenders deducted for not having a valid clearance certificate. This thus positively affects small firms’ cash flows and ultimately their profitability levels. “Theoretically that is the case but practically it’s a different story altogether as ZIMRA takes for ever to process VAT refunds or worse still your refund claim can be an “invitation” to come and scrutinise your transactions” said TEX3. A view affirmed by the majority of the tax experts and all IS association members. ZIMRA officers on the other hand acknowledged the multiplicity of taxes but argued that those taxes must be viewed differently as income tax on employment was tax on employees’ incomes and VAT was merely a transmission of tax collected to consumers to ZIMRA. ZIMRAO5 asseverated that “perhaps presumptive taxes and the 2% transaction tax can be argued to be from the same income but VAT is paid by consumers of products and employment income is in principle being paid by the employees as it is part of their gross income anywhere.” In light of the discussion it was apparent that the multiplicity of taxes is burdensome on the informal firms this crippling their operations and leaving little or no funds for working capital, growth and continuity needs. This observation is similar to submissions by Cheeseman and Griffiths (2005) who expressed the negative impact of formalisation and tax administration on the IS positing that informal firms exist because if they were to be formalised, they would fail to achieve profitability and collapse resulting in the loss of “informal jobs”. TEX5 insisted that despite the heavy burden imposed by the 2% IMTT, if registered for tax purposes and formalised, an informal firm’s payment of remuneration of are exempt from the 2% tax. Considering the informal firms are very small and pay very low incomes the exemption would still be very minimal amounts.
 
Disincentive to investment
 
It was established that the current IS taxation framework acted as a disincentive to investment. Taxes were attested to have an effect of reducing the return on investment (ROI). It was also considered unfair to informal firms who do not enjoy benefits that go hand in hand with capital investments such as special initial allowance or wear and tear awarded to their formal counterparts as allowable deductions and in the case of miners the capital redemption allowance (CRA) in terms of the Income Tax Act, Zimbabwe (Chapter 23:06). This discourages the IS from investing and having fixed abodes. One IS sector association member expressed that “our sector is not given the same privileges of tax holidays, incentives, tax deductions and given to the formal sector; hence it is difficult for our members to invest or even acquire fixed assets. Government should consider that our businesses are small and enable us instead of killing the businesses through heavy taxes”. This resonates with submissions in relation to SME growth by Machira (2007) who advances that tax policy has an unfavourable influence on the growth and going concern of the small businesses, as it reduces sales, capital, profits and thus affecting investment decisions
 
Garnishees lead to the collapse of small firms
 
The other notable findings from TEXs were that registration for tax purposes and tax compliance minimised the unnecessary garnishees and penalties by ZIMRA which often compromised the survival of the IS firms. It also helped in the avoidance of “greasing the palms” of tax officers as way to cover up for non-tax compliance.  The IS association members expressed views to the contrary arguing that registering for taxes actually opened crevices for the ZIMRA garnishees as due to the instability of incomes in the IS, the informal firms always struggle to pay their tax obligations and penalties. This leads to ZIMRA garnishing them as the tax collectors just want tax money even when cash flows are low, on the basis that income has been received or accrued s defined by Income Tax Act. ISAM4 raised the following concern, “imagine you are expecting to receive a payment and you have made plans to purchase raw materials, settle creditors and other operational costs and suddenly ZIMRA garnishes you through your bank and all that income is gone. The impact that such a move will have on your business and plans is just bad, especially for small businesses such as ours.”  The challenge was not only viewed from the garnishees side by the IS associations, but also increased extortions highlighted as one factor that crippled the operation of the IS in Zimbabwe. 90% of the tax experts strongly agreed that registration for tax purposes on the contrary exposed registered small companies to harassment and predatory behaviour of revenue officers. “These corrupt  ZIMRA officers often exploit the lack of tax knowledge by these taxpayers and in their calculations of liabilities and penalties, they often show huge figures so as to convince the taxpayers that they will save by paying bribes as the debt would be reduced or concealed” said a TEX7. The majority of tax experts equally shared similar opinions. Most revenue officers had a different view of things though acknowledging them maybe bad apples in the system, they argued that corruption does exist but in most cases the general public is against the coercive nature of tax collection, yet this is should be expected.
 
Development of a conceptual framework
 
A schematic portrayal of the relationship between IS taxation and growth which is measured in terms of vectors profitability, capital investment and asset growth is presented in Figure 5 in a conceptual framework to guide derived the study. Tax policy should aim to balance the need to mobilise revenue and other reasons for taxation. To do so, policy makers can use the following framework in guiding policy formulation as well as evaluating the impact of tax policy.
 


 CONCLUSIONS AND LIMITATIONS

The answers to the question, if an avenue for an expansive tax base or hindering the growth of small firms or both? could be disparate depending on the contextual environments. For instance one could argue for both, depending on tax policy, the structure and design of the IS taxation framework, its administration and implementation (how burdensome it is, in terms of the tax rates, compliance costs versus the incomes/profit from the sector). Secondly, how incentivising is the taxation framework (tax incentives, exemptions and allowable deductions; chances of business development, training programmes and access to financing). Lastly the economic, political and social realities in the country will provide contextual answers to the question. In Zimbabwe, this study concludes that the IS taxation framework in its current state has not resulted in a meaningful expanded tax base but instead it could be crippling the IS operations, increasing tax evasions and compounding SMEs’ mortality rates, as expressed in the opinions of stakeholders interviewed. This conclusion though has a limitation that the failure of small firms can be linked to many other factors such poor accounting skills and financial management as well as lack of adequate capital. Expansion of the IS absorbs unemployment to a large extent, to the relief of policy makers, the same IS creates a “fiscal gap” that undermines policy makers’ objective  of widening the tax base. Tax policy should focus on revenue generation and its relationship with the construction of productive capacities of small firms. The argument albeit, does not infer that formalisation will automatically expand the tax base; therefore efforts have to be made into building a tax compliance culture. To reduce the fiscal gap and excessive foreign financing that often lead to the problem of debt sustainability, domestic revenue mobilisation has to be improved by taxing the IS. Non-payment of taxes by the IS kills the tax morale of compliant firms in the formal sector. Lower tax compliance morale leads to a rise in tax evasion and avoidance as well as a fall in tax revenue. On the other hand, excessive tax and the one size fits all kind of taxation cripples the growth, survival and profitability of IS firms. The absence of tax exemptions and tax holidays for the IS in most developing countries hampers enlargement of IS firms. On equity grounds, low incomes, large IS, poor tax administration and unproductive businesses have potentially resulted in the formal sector being burdened through VAT, corporate tax and excise duties. The pertinent question is, how then do developing country governments expand the tax base without obstructing the survival and growth of the IS? A keen appreciation of the  imperatives  entailed  in the different perspectives in favour of and against IS taxation is vital for any reconciliation of the divergent policy prescriptions towards IS taxation. According to Oviedo et al. (2009), policy packages need to be adapted to the characteristics of informality in a country. In some countries regulatory reform might be more appropriate, while in others regulator enforcement or IS tax framework restructure might be more relevant. The common denominator of the various policy prescriptions is the realisation that the IS cannot be dismissed out of hand, it has grown to the extent that it warrants serious attention and consideration for both taxation and economic growth. The challenge remains how to balance the revenue mobilisation agenda with the need to promote growth and survival in the sector in Zimbabwe considering the current unfavourable impact.


 RECOMMENDATIONS

The findings of the study acknowledge the role played by the IS in the economy and that unfavourable tax policies can have a detrimental effect on the on the sector’s growth and its development and the economy at large. If taxes are responsible for the high SMEs mortality rates, then it are essential for government-stakeholder consultation on the impact of presumptive taxes on the growth and survival of IS operators. The study makes the following contributions:
 
1. Revisit the current design of IS tax policy (assess whether it is optimal or there are other alternatives). There is need for reforms on the current IS taxation framework in Zimbabwe, it is essential to consider the ability to pay when designing tax policy. Setting a level of growth limit or turnover which can be viewed as adequate to sustain payment of taxes, payment of tax obligations in instalments is another angle to address the problem. In relation to designing of IS tax policy, Deloitte (2015) suggested the need for stratification of IS operators in order to ensure appropriate focus and strategies are employed towards taxing the sector arguing that in most developing countries profit margins earned by firms in the sector are not matching the relatively high tax rates levied in the sector.
2. Stakeholder consultations and discussion on IS tax policy design and impact. Inclusivity of tax policy, understanding and acceptance can be best fostered through government, tax administrators and IS consultative engagement which is key to inclusive tax policy.
3. Reduce multiplicity of taxes. There is need for the Zimbabwe government to revisit it taxation structures especially on the multiplicity of taxes. The 2% IMTT transaction tax recently implemented  has  compounded the impact of taxes on the survival of small firms. Despite the benefits of formalisation and registering for tax purposes that were highlighted especially by tax experts in the study, these are difficult for the IS to access due to several reasons such as tax education inadequacies and low incomes that cannot sustain formal requirements and multiple taxes. It is therefore important for policymakers to consider designing tax incentives that are targeting the informal firms in their informal state without forcing them to formalise. Cheeseman and Griffiths (2005) cautioned against forcing informal firms to formalise adducing that some of them are only viable, operational and profitable because they are informal otherwise forced formalisation would suffocate them.
4. Nurture the IS. Government to desist from a single minded focus on revenue collections but nurture the IS firms through incentives, skills empowerment programmes on record keeping, financial management, cost and management accounting as well as tax technical knowledge,  access to credit and other financing programs.  Nanthuru et al (2018) highlight the need for developing countries’ government to offer training programs of risk management and accounting to equip SMEs to mitigate business risks and risks such as tax. Developing countries could borrow from emerging economies like China where tax policies are designed with the objective to enhance growth of small firms. For example their tax policy awards allowable tax deductions to institutions and venture who invest in SMEs up to a maximum of 70% of the invested amount (Ocheni and Gemade, 2015; Ameyaw et al., 2016). This view of supporting and nurturing informal firms was affirmed by Cheeseman and Griffiths (2005) who argued that in highlighting the failure to pay taxes by the IS  policy makers tend to ignore the dichotomy of denied finance and services as well as proper infrastructure that results in low productivity and low incomes, hence the failure to pay tax.  The researchers suggest that the equation should start from government support in the form of financing and infrastructure to aid in the transition from informal to formal in order to preserve the survival of informal firms.
5. Consider tax holidays, tax exemptions and incentives for the IS. Considering the submissions by researchers such as La Porta and Shliefer (2014) that the informal firms are too inefficient to operate under formal platforms without being enfeebled by the formalisation costs, developing country governments should try to give the informal firms access to some of the tax concessions rendered to the formal sector for example the allowable deductions, tax holidays and tax incentives. While others view informality with the eyes of inefficiency others argue the informal firms are productive enough and efficient enough for their size, all they need is for tax policy to be  accommodative  and  also  give  them   access   to  social security platforms.
6. Conduct more research on IS tax policy and continuously evaluates it. There is need for more research on the tax rates and their impact on the IS. The introduction of presumptive taxes, in 2005, was informed by research carried out by the Zimbabwe Revenue Authority (ZIMRA) on informal urban transport operators as opined by Dube and Casale (2016). However, indications are that subsequently, no research was done by ZIMRA on the profitability of the other sub-sectors that were later added to the presumptive tax. Bearing in mind that the economic environment and business world is dynamic it would be noble to revisit the policy and assess it for suitability, effectiveness and impact. There is also need for more research on how to formulate an optimal  informal sector policy as well as the nature of  the tax incentives that can be awarded to the IS in order to boost both the growth of informal firms and tax compliance. Future researchers could also focus on the best way to tax the IS, whether to do it through direct or indirect taxation.


 CONFLICT OF INTERESTS

The author has not declared any conflict of interests.



 REFERENCES

Adebisi J, Gbegi D (2013). Effect of multiple taxation on the performance of small and medium scale business enterprises.(A study of West African Ceremics Ajeokuta, Kogi State). Mediterranean Journal of Social Sciences 4(6):323.
Crossref

 

Ameyaw B, Korang JA, Twum ET, Asante IO (2016). Tax policy, SMEs compliance, perception and growth relationship in Ghana: an empirical analysis. Journal of Economics, Management and Trade pp. 1-11.
Crossref

 
 

Arosanyin G, Ijaiya G, Oludoyi S, Ajayi M, Ipingbemi O (2009). Government Assistance for Informal Sector Enterprises in Nigeria: A Case Study of Tire Repair Services in Illorin, Kwara State. Ghana Journal of Development Studies 6(2).
Crossref

 
 

Atawadi OW, Ojeka S (2012a). Factors that affect tax compliance among small and medium enterprises (SMEs) in North Central Nigeria. International Journal of Business and Management 7(12).
Crossref

 
 

Atawadi OW, Ojeka SA (2012b). Relationship between Tax Policy, Growth of SMEs and the Nigerian Economy. International Journal of Business and Management 7(13):125-135.
Crossref

 
 

Ayee JR (2007). Building tax compliance through reciprocity with Government. Enterprise Formalization in Africa pp. 6-7.

 
 

Benjamin NC, Mbaye AA (2012). The Informal Sector, Productivity, and Enforcement in West Africa: A Firm?level Analysis. Review of Development Economics 16(4):664-680.
Crossref

 
 

Bhattacharya D, Akbar MI (2014). Domestic Resource Mobilisation in the LDCs: Trends, Determinants and Challenges. Istanbul Programme of Action for the LDCs 422 p.

 
 

Bhorat H, Naidoo K, Ewinyu A (2017). Increasing Employment Opportunities: Navigating Africa's Complex Job Market.

View

 
 

Biles JJ (2008). Informal Work and Livelihoods in Mexico: Getting By or Getting Ahead?. The Professional Geographer 60(4):541-555.
Crossref

 
 

Bird R, Wallace S (2003). Is it really so hard to tax the hard-to-tax? The context and role of presumptive taxes. ITP Paper, 307 p.
Crossref

 
 

Bruhn M (2013). A tale of two species: Revisiting the effect of registration reform on informal business owners in Mexico. Journal of Development Economics 103:275-283.
Crossref

 
 

Bruhn M, Loeprick J (2014). Small Business Tax Policy, Informality, and Tax Evasion-Evidence from Georgia.
Crossref

 
 

Bruhn M, McKenzie D (2014). Entry regulation and the formalization of microenterprises in developing countries. The World Bank Research Observer 29(2):186-201.
Crossref

 
 

Buehn A, Schneider F (2012). Size and Development of Tax Evasion in 38 OECD Countries: What do we (not) know?

 
 

Charema (2014). Taxation stifles SMEs growth. 

 
 

Cheeseman N, Griffiths N (2005). Increasing Tax revenue in sub Saharan Africa. The case of Kenya. Oxford Council on Good Governance OCGG Economy Analysis 6 p.

 
 

Creswell JW (2014). Research Design: Qualitative, Quantitative and Mixed Approaches. 4th Edition. Thousand Oaks: SAGE

 
 

Creswell JW, Fetters MD, Plano Clark VL, Morales A (2009). Mixed methods intervention trials. Mixed methods research for nursing and the healthsciences, pp. 161-180.
Crossref

 
 

Creswell JW (2016). "Reflections on the MMIRA. The Future of Mixed Methods Taskforce Report 10(3):215-219. 
Crossref

 
 

Dalu T, Maposa VG, Dalu T, Pabwaungana S (2013). Awareness and compliance levels of informal traders with regards to their presumptive tax obligations: a case of Harare central business district informal traders. African Journal of Economic and Sustainable Development 2(4):297-308.
Crossref

 
 

Davis LS (2007). Explaining the evidence on inequality and growth: informality and redistribution. The BE Journal of Macroeconomics 7(1).
Crossref

 
 

De Mel S, McKenzie DJ, Woodruff C (2009). Measuring microenterprise profits: Must we ask how the sausage is made? Journal of Development Economics 88(1):19-31.
Crossref

 
 

De Mel S, McKenzie D, Woodruff C (2013). The demand for, and consequences of, formalization among informal firms in Sri Lanka. American Economic Journal: Applied Economics 5(2):122-150.
Crossref

 
 

De Paula A, Scheinkman JA (2011). The informal sector: An equilibrium model and some empirical evidence from Brazil. Review of Income and Wealth 57(s1):S8-S26.
Crossref

 
 

Deloitte (2015). Harnessing the bottom billions in the informalsector: Are tax authorities wiling to engage. www.deloitte.com/content/dam/Deloitte/Documents/tax/inside-tax/ng-harnessing-the-bottom-billions

 
 

Di John J (2009). Taxation, Resource Mobilisation, and Productive Capacity-Building in LDCs. Study prepared for UNCTAD as a background paper for The Least Developed Countries Report.

 
 

Dickerson CM (2014). Bringing formal business laws to Cameroon's informal sector: lessons and cautions from the tax law example. Washington University Global Studies Law Review 13:265.

 
 

Douglas EJ (2013). Reconstructing entrepreneurial intentions to identify predisposition for growth. Journal of Business Venturing 28(5):633-651.
Crossref

 
 

Dube G (2014). Informal sector tax administration in Zimbabwe. Public Administration and Development 34(1):48-62.
Crossref

 
 

Dube G, Casale D (2016). The implementation of informal sector taxation: Evidence from selected African countries. eJournal of Tax Research 14(3):601.

 
 

Ebeke C, Ehrhart H (2012). Tax revenue instability in Sub-saharan Africa: Consequences and remedies. Journal of African Economies 21(1):1-27.
Crossref

 
 

Engelschalk M (2007). Designing a tax system for micro and small businesses: guide for practitioners.

 
 

Engelschalk M, Loeprick J (2016). The taxation of micro and small businesses in transition economies: Country experience of the introduction of special tax regimes. Journal of Tax Administration 2(1):145-197.
Crossref

 
 

Evans C, Hansford A, Hasseldine J, Lignier P, Smulders S, Vaillancourt F (2014). Small business and tax compliance costs: A cross-country study of managerial benefits and tax concessions. European Journal of Tourism Research 12:453.

 
 

Evans M, Syrett S, Williams C (2006). Informal economic activities and deprived neighbourhoods.

 
 

Fajnzylber P, Maloney WF, Montes-Rojas GV (2009). Releasing constraints to growth or pushing on a string? Policies and performance of Mexican micro-firms. The Journal of Development Studies 45(7):1027-1047.
Crossref

 
 

Farzbod J (2000). Investigation of the Effective Factors in the Tax Efficiency. Unpublished master's thesis, Governmental Management Training Center, Tehran.

 
 

Feyitimi O, Temitope OA, Akeem LB, Samuel O (2016). Tax Incentives and the Growth of Small and Medium Scale Enterprises in Developing Economy-The Nigerian Experience. European Journal of Research and Reflection in Management Sciences 4(2).

 
 

Fjeldstad OH, Kolstad I, Nygaard K (2006). Bribes, taxes and regulations: Business constraints for micro enterprises in Tanzania: Chr. Michelsen Institute.

 
 

Fourie F (2018). Creating jobs, reducing poverty: why the informal sector should be taken seriously and enabled properly.

 
 

Fox L (2009). Sharing the Growth in Uganda: Recent Labor Market Outcomes and Poverty Reduction, Draft Note (Unpublished).

 
 

Fox L, Pimhidzai O (2011). Is informality welfare-enhancing structural transformation? Evidence from Uganda. Evidence from Uganda (October 1, 2011). World Bank Policy Research Working Paper Series (5866).
Crossref

 
 

Fusch PI, Ness LR (2015). Are we there yet? Data saturation in qualitative research. Qualitative Report 20(9):1408.
Crossref

 
 

Gerxhani K (2004). The informal sector in developed and less developed countries: a literature survey. Public choice 120(3-4):267-300.
Crossref

 
 

Gordon R, Li W (2009). Tax structures in developing countries: Many puzzles and a possible explanation. Journal of public Economics 93(7):855-866.
Crossref

 
 

Guest G, Namey E, Chen M (2020). A simple method to assess and report thematic saturation in qualitative research. PloS One 15(5):e0232076.
Crossref

 
 

Gurtoo A, Williams CC (2009). Entrepreneurship and the informal sector: some lessons from India. The International Journal of Entrepreneurship and Innovation 10(1):55-62.
Crossref

 
 

Heggstad KK, Ustvedt T, Myhrvold-Hanssen TL, Briseid M (2011). Towards fiscal self-reliance: Capacity building for domestic revenue enhancement in Mozambique, Tanzania and Zambia (Workshop report).

 
 
 

Holban OI (2007). The Taxation of Small and Medium- Sized Enterprises- a Hindering Fctor Influencing the European Economic Growth. Doctoral Dossertation, University Iasi and Academy of Economies Studies from Bucharest Romania.

 
 

Joshi A, Ayee J (2008). Associational taxation: A pathway into the informal sector? Taxation and State-Building in Developing Countries pp. 183-211.
Crossref

 
 

Joshi A, Prichard W, Heady C (2013). Taxing the Informal Economy: Challenges, Possibilities and Remaining Questions. IDS Working Papers 429:1-37. 
Crossref

 
 

Joshi A, Prichard W, Heady C (2014). Taxing the informal economy: The current state of knowledge and agendas for future research. The Journal of Development Studies 50(10):1325-1347.
Crossref

 
 

Kanbur R, Keen M (2014). Thresholds, informality, and partitions of compliance. International Tax and Public Finance 21(4):536-559. 
Crossref

 
 

Keen M (2012). Taxation and development: Again. International Monetary Fund.
Crossref

 
 

Kenyon T, Kapaz E (2005). The Informality Trap. Small 10:49.

 
 

Kristoffersen S (2011). Taxation and informal sector growth in developing countries (Master's thesis).

 
 

La Porta R, Shleifer A (2014). Informality and development. Journal of Economic Perspectives 28(3):109-126.
Crossref

 
 

Ligomeka W (2019). Expensive to be a Female Trader: The Reality of Taxation of Flea Market Traders in Zimbabwe.

View

 
 

Liu X (2014). Use tax compliance: The role of norms, audit probability, and sanction severity. Academy of Accounting and Financial Studies Journal 18(1):65-80.

 
 

Machemedze R, Wadzanai S, Zhou J, Chirisa I (2018). Informal Economy and Social Vulnerability in Zimbabwe, Research Report. Friedrich-Ebert-Stiftung, Zimbabwe.

 
 

Machira JM (2007). Taxation and the SMEs Sector Growth. Asian Journal of Business and Management Sciences 2(3):1-7.

 
 

Maina AW (2017). The effect of consumption taxes on poverty and income inequality in Kenya. International Journal of Accounting and Taxation 5(2):56-82.
Crossref

 
 

Maina AW (2014). Income taxes and economic performance in Kenya (Doctoral dissertation).

 
 

Maloney WF (2004). Informality revisited. World Development 32(7):1159-1178.
Crossref

 
 

Mangwana N (2016). Small businesses are a big deal. 

 
 

Manyani O, Onias Z, Hove N, Mudzura M, Chiriseri L (2014). An investigation into venture financing: A case study on small to medium scale enterprises in Bindura urban, Zimbabwe (2013-2014).

 
 

Martinez-Vazquez J, Bird RM (2014). Sustainable development requires a good tax system. Taxation and Develpoment: The Weakest Link 1A26.
Crossref

 
 

Masarirambi C (2013). An investigation into factors associated with tax evasion in the Zimbabwe informal sector: A survey of Magaba Mbare informal traders. PhD thesis, Zimbabwe Open University, Harare.

 
 

Masato A (2009). Globalisation of Production and Competitiveness of Small and Medium sized Enterprises in Asia and the Pacific: Trends and Prospects. Publication of United Nations Economic and Social Commission for Asia and the Pacific, Studies in Trade and Investment (1):1-31.

 
 

Mbiliayi A (2012). Progress in Taxing the Informal Sector case of Tanzania. TJN-A newsletter. Second quarter, 3.

 
 

McCulloch N, Grover A (2010). Estimating the national impact of the financial crisis in Indonesia by combining a rapid qualitative study with nationally representative surveys. IDS Working Papers 346:01-39.
Crossref

 
 

McKenzie D, Sakho YS (2010). Does it pay firms to register for taxes?

 
 

The impact of formality on firm profitability. Journal of Development Economics 91(1):15-24.

 
 

McKerchar MA (2008). Philosophical Paradigms, Inquiry Strategies and Knowledge Claims: Applying the Principles of Research Design and Conduct to Taxation. eJournal of Tax Research 6(1):5-22. UNSW Law Research Paper No. 2009-31.

 
 

Meagher K (2018). Taxing times: Taxation, divided societies and the informal economy in Northern Nigeria. The Journal of Development Studies 54(1):1-17. 
Crossref

 
 

Meagher K, Lindell I (2013). ASR forum: engaging with african informal economies: social inclusion or adverse incorporation? Introduction. African Studies Review 56(3):57-76. 
Crossref

 
 

Medina L, Schneider F (2018). Shadow economies around the world: what did we learn over the last 20 years? IMF Working Paper No 18/17.
Crossref

 
 

Millin M, Coetzee C (2007). Informal (Business) Sector Survey for Hibiscus Coast Local Municipality: Pietermaritzburg: Landmark.

 
 

Moyi E, Ronge E (2006). Taxation and Tax Modernization in Kenya: A Diagnosis of Performance and Options for Further Reform. Institute of Economic Affairs, Nairobi, Kenya.

 
 

Mpapale C (2014). Broadening the tax base in Kenya: The case of the informal sector (A diagnosis of current practice and a prognosis of reform options). The East Africa Tax and Governance Network (EATGN).

 
 

Mungaya M, Mbwambo AH, Tripathi SK (2012). Study of tax system impact on the growth of small and medium enterprises (SMEs): with reference to Shinyanga Municipality, Tanzania. International Journal of Management and Business Studies 2(3)99-105.

 
 

Munjeyi E (2017). Informal Sector Taxation: Is There Anything Worth Research. Research Journal of Accounting and Finance 8(20).

 
 

Munjeyi E, Maponga S, Piki R, Thusabantu L, Mutasa S (2017). Creating A 'Tax Paying Informal Traders' Culture In Zimbabwe:Can This Be Achievable? Research Journal of Finance and Accounting 8(1):9. 

 
 

Nanthuru SB, Pingfeng L, Guihua N, Mkonya VL (2018). An Assessment of Risk Management Practices of SME Taxpayers in Malawi and their Impact on Tax Compliance. International Journal of Management Sciences and Business Administration 4(4):7-17.
Crossref

 
 

Neneh BN, Vanzyl J (2014). Growth intention and its impact on business growth amongst SMEs in South Africa. Mediterranean Journal of Social Sciences 5(20):172.
Crossref

 
 

Ocheni S, Gemade TI (2015). Effects of Multiple Taxation on the Performance of Small and Medium Scale Business Enterprises in Benue State. International Journal of Academic Research in Business and Social Sciences 5(3):345-364.
Crossref

 
 

Ojeka S (2011). Tax Policy and the Growth of SMEs: Implications for the Nigerian Economy. Research Journal of Finance and Accounting 2(2).

 
 

Ordóñez JCL (2014). Tax collection, the informal sector, and productivity. Review of Economic Dynamics 17(2):262-286.
Crossref

 
 

Oviedo AM, Thomas MR, Karakurum-Ozdemir K (2009). Economic informality: causes, costs, and policies-a literature survey: The World Bank.
Crossref

 
 

Perry G, Maloney W, Arias O, Fajnzylber P, Mason A, Saavedra J (2007). Informality: Exit and Exclusion, World Bank Latin America and Caribbean Studies. World Bank, Washington DC.
Crossref

 
 

Pimhidzai O, Fox L (2011). Taking from the poor or local economic development: the dilemma of taxation of small informal enterprises in Uganda. World Bank Africa Regional Project on Improving the Productivity and Reducing Risk of Household Enterprises, Washington DC.

 
 
 

Prichard W (2009). Taxation and Development in Ghana: Finance, equity and accountability.
Crossref

 
 

Rogan M (2019). Tax Justice and the Informal Economy: A Review of the debates. WIEGO Working Paper No 41.

 
 

Rutasitara l (2014). Feasibility of Taxing the Informal Sector: a survey with reflections on Tanzania longinus rutasitara. Zambia Social Science Journal 3(1) (April 2012), 23.

 
 

Sabot R (1973). Employment, incomes and equality: A strategy for increasing productive employment in Kenya: Geneva: ILO, 1972. Pp. xx+ 600. [UK pound] 3.96. World Development 1(6):78-80.
Crossref

 
 

Schneider F (2002). The size and development of the shadow economies of 22 transition and 21 OECD countries.

 
 

Schneider F, Enste DH (2013). The shadow economy: An international survey. Cambridge University Press.
Crossref

 
 

Sebele-Mpofu FY (2021). The Informal Sector, the "implicit" Social Contract, the Willingness to Pay Taxes and Tax Compliance in Zimbabwe. Accounting, Economics, and Law: A Convivium 1(ahead-of-print). 
Crossref

 
 

Sebele-Mpofu FY (2020). Governance quality and tax morale and compliance in Zimbabwe's informal sector. Cogent Business & Management 7(1):1794662.
Crossref

 
 

Sebele-Mpofu FY, Msipa C (2011). Feasibility of Administering Informal Sector Taxation: Approaches and Hurdles. A Case of the Informal Sector in Bulawayo, Zimbabwe. 

 
 

Shahrodi SMM (2010). Investigation of the effective factors in the efficiency of tax system. Journal of Accounting and Taxation 2(3):42-45.

 
 

Sikwila MN, Kareza G, Mungadza A (2016), 'Tax collection constraints and tax burden on the ubarn informalsector', Enterprises: evidence from Bulawayo Zimbabwe. Mediterranean Journal of Social Sciences 7(6).
Crossref

 
 

Smith A (1776). The wealth ofnations. New York: The Modern Library.

 
 

Soest CV (2007). Measuring the capability to raise revenue: Process and output dimensions and their application to the Zambia Revenue Authority. Public Administration and Development 27(4):353-365.
Crossref

 
 

Tax Matrix (2019). Tax incentives for small and mediun enterprises.

View

 
 

Tee E, Boadi L, Opoku R (2016). The effect of tax payment on the performance of SMEs: the case of selected SMEs in Ga west municipal assembly. European Journal of Business and Management 8(20).

 
 

Terkper S (2003). Managing small and medium-size taxpayers in developing economies. Tax notes international 29(2):211-229.

 
 

Thomas KD (2013). Presumptive Collection: A Prospect Theory Approach to Increasing Small Business Tax Compliance. Tax Law Review 67:111.

 
 

Tomlin B (2008). Clearing hurdles: Key reforms to make small businesses more succesful. Howe Institute. Toronto.

View

 
 

Torgler B (2005). Tax morale in Latin America. Public choice 122(1-2):133-157.
Crossref

 
 

Torgler B, Schneider F (2009). The impact of tax morale and institutional quality on the shadow economy. Journal of Economic Psychology 30(2):228-245.
Crossref

 
 

Toye J (2000). Fiscal crisis and fiscal reform in developing countries. Cambridge Journal of Economics 24(1)21-44.
Crossref

 
 

Twesige D, Gasheja F (2019). Effect of tax incentives on the growth of small and medium-sized enterprises (SMEs) in Rwanda: A case study of SMEs in Nyarugenge district. Journal of Accounting and Taxation 11(5):89-98.
Crossref

 
 

Twesige D, Gasheja F, Barayendema J (2020). Tax Incentives and Growth of SMEs in Rwanda: A Case Study of Small and Medium Enterprises in Nyarugenge District Rwandan Economy at the Crossroads of Development: Springer pp. 231-247.
Crossref

 
 

Udoh JE (2015). Taxing the Informal Economy in Nigeria: Issues, Challenges and Opportunities.

 
 

Van den Boogaard V, Prichard W, Jibao S (2018). Informal taxation in Sierra Leone: Magnitudes, perceptions and implications. African Affairs 118(471):259-284.
Crossref

 
 

Von Soest C (2007). How does neopatrimonialism affect the African state's revenues? The case of tax collection in Zambia. The journal of modern African studies 45(4):621-645.
Crossref

 
 

Wafula WJ (2013). The Place of Small and Medium Enterprises in Economic Development: A Kenyan Perspective. Clear International Journal of Research in Commerce and Management 4(8).

 
 

Woodruff C (2013). Registering for Growth: Tax and the Informal Sector in Developing Countries. The CAGE-Chatham House Series 7(2):12.

 
 

World Bank (2011). Tax Perceptions and Compliance Costs Survey. A Tool for Tax Reform.

Crossref

 
 

Zohrabi M (2013). Mixed Method Research: Instruments, Validity, Reliability and Reporting Findings. Theory and Practice in Language Studies 3(2):254-262. 
Crossref

 

 




          */?>