African Journal of
Business Management

  • Abbreviation: Afr. J. Bus. Manage.
  • Language: English
  • ISSN: 1993-8233
  • DOI: 10.5897/AJBM
  • Start Year: 2007
  • Published Articles: 4190

Full Length Research Paper

Transaction costs and competitive tendering in public procurement: Moderating role of integrity

Sama Hamisi
  • Sama Hamisi
  • Procurement and Supplies Department, College of Business Education, Dodoma Campus, P. O. Box 2077, Dodoma, Tanzania.
  • Google Scholar
Ndunguru Philibert
  • Ndunguru Philibert
  • Faculty of Science and Technology, Mzumbe University P. O. Box 6, Mzumbe, Morogoro, Tanzania.
  • Google Scholar
Nsimbila Paul
  • Nsimbila Paul
  • Department of Procurement and Logistics, School of Business, Mzumbe University, P. O. Box 6, Mzumbe, Morogoro, Tanzania.
  • Google Scholar


  •  Received: 22 April 2021
  •  Accepted: 06 April 2022
  •  Published: 30 June 2022

 ABSTRACT

While the current economic crisis clearly puts pressure on governments to cut spending and save money, and whilst the call for a more cohesive interface between the public and private sectors is currently resonating, public procurement has been marred by scandals, mismanagement, and possibly malpractices. According to the literature, corporate integrity drives transactional behaviors by acting as a hidden hand of social factors that are frequently beyond an individual's control. But scantly studied, as behavioral control mechanism in transaction costs. This paper studies the moderating effect of integrity on the relationship between transaction costs’ behavioral dimensions and competitive tendering in public procurement. Following a literature review, the paper takes a conceptual framework towards developing evidence of cascaded transaction costs’ behavioral dimensions, bounded rationality and opportunism. Formal research propositions amplify both concepts and its relationship with independent variable and dependent variables. The results are based on the empirical data collected from a self-administrative survey from public procurement practitioners in Tanzania. Descriptive and Hierarchical regression results reveals that public procurement practitioners’ perceived transaction costs to negatively when related with competitive tendering as moderated by integrity. This means, integrity can moderate the behaviors of public procurement practitioner which, in turn, accelerates efficiency of competitive tendering by reducing transaction costs.

 

Key words: Transaction costs, competitive tendering, integrity, public procurement.


 INTRODUCTION

Historically, public entities in most countries have been known for their poor performance and corruption, resulting from behavioral malpractices evidenced among the procurement practitioners when carrying out procurement contracts (Achua, 2011; Kutosi et al., 2015). It was noted that present day business environment is characterized by an expanding number of scandals in public procurement when competitive tendering is applied in obtaining requirements (Schapper et al., 2006; Ntayi et al., 2013). The problems of  integrity  and competitive tendering implications’ on public procurement has been identified by many as not only enormous and complex but also seriously endangered various governments to provide more services with little funds (McCrudden and Gross, 2006; Yakovlev et al., 2015). It was observe that organised and executed procurement process will make it possible for individuals to decrease opportunistic behaviour, diminish bounded rationality as well as reduces transaction costs in competitive tendering (Lingard et al., 1998; Amaral et al., 2009). Otherwise, from the long term perspective, competitive tendering process may fail significantly to promote effective public procurement outcomes (Caldwell et al., 2005; Hensher and Wallis, 2005).

 

Over the last few decades till recently, there has been growing interest of integrity in public procurement as many authors have been discussing an immediate effect on the public service delivery (Eyaa and Oluka, 2011; Arrowsmith et al., 2000). Starting with the behaviour and morality literature (Cox et al., 2003; Jensen, 2009; Erhard et al., 2008), a solid ground of theoretical and empirical literature has already been set for the use of integrity theories in organisation behaviour. In this way, integrity concept have more and more been adopted and applied in actual business practice.

 

For that fact, different integrity concepts such as moral standards and values (von Hippel, 2001), transparency (Barnard, et al., 2008), trust (Frankel, 2005), ethical compliance (Eisenbeib and Brodbeck, 2014), and honesty (Frankel, 2005) have been widely used as guidance against malpractices. In some procuring entities are even more successful with the efficiency and performance, and especially ethical compliance (Jibrin et al., 2014; Amemba et al., 2013), mostly due to their higher application of integrity. In effect, integrity is an important factor of efficiency and performance, yet its major role in efficiency and performance in competitive tendering has been largely hidden or unnoticed, or even ignored in reduction of transaction costs. Hence, integrity in competitive tendering has been unrecognized as a most actively researched field, giving public procurement an even more solid theoretical foundation. While several articles have dealt with the concept of integrity (Menzel, 2015); Ugwu, 2018) and brought it to a wider audience (Chesbrough, 2006), a holistic approach to the future disciplines of public procurement has yet to be developed by the scientific community.

 

Integrity is the perception that another person, group, or entity lives by his word – delivers on promises and enacts the same espoused values (Palanski and Yammarino, 2011; Childers, 2009). In fact, integrity shows perceived pattern of alignment between words and deeds in business transactions (Prottas, 2008; Palanski et al., 2011). Different empirical studies have shown powerful consequences for the integrity and performance of individuals in business practices, and also that integrity moderates the impact of practitioners’ behaviours on transactional outcomes. Only a few studies have examined antecedents, and fewer still have examined moderated antecedents of integrity in public procurement and behavioral practices. Although initial terrain has been scantly sketched out by early studies, there is much yet to learn about the workings of moderation effect of integrity on transaction costs in competitive tendering.

 

The debate over transaction costs on competitive tendering issue is crucial, as clarity over the challenges and objectives of the integrity in procurement process is critical to the delivery of satisfactory outcomes because competitive tendering on public procurement are estimated around 1.6% of the contract value (Musanzikwa, 2013; Jur?ík, 2014). Such costs are borne by all participants in the procurement process, including suppliers and procurement regulators, in addition to public customers. According to Jur?ík  (2014) existence of transaction costs in public procurement is based on imperfect contracts are due to the limited rationality of individuals, and these agreements suffer from necessity of additional costs (bounded rationality) and benefits extension may be carried out by using methods that are not entirely moral, and in some cases even not legal (opportunism). Therefore, understanding the key characteristics of a transaction can help decision-makers improve the design of contracts, organizations, and other governance structures that could reduce competitive tendering and improve the gains from an exchange between buyers and sellers (Williamson, 2008).

 

For some cases, integrity in actual business practice has been widely recognized as a source of assurance of confidence, efficiency and performance and successful applied on enhancing trust (Kauppi and Van Raaij, 2015), compliance, ethics and professional values (Lennick and Kiel, 2007; Arjoon, 2005). However, public entities in most countries have been known for their poor performance and corruption, resulting from non-adherence to processes and procedures, poor resource utilisation, and malpractices (Amemba et al., 2013; Naidoo, 2012). Nevertheless, researchers have established that integrity constitute an essential element of efficiency of competitive tendering and costs savings in public procurement (Kauppi and Van Raaij, 2015; Merry et al., 2012). This acknowledgement forms central role of on increasing costs such as TCs in a public procurement process results from discontent with cognitive explanations of integrity in CTP (Ntayi et al., 2013, Balogun, 2003). Thus, initiatives of stressing savings with less costs in government tends to be unattainable (Alford and Hughes, 2008; Evenett, 2002). In this way, inventiveness of providing more public services with less public spending is an ongoing challenge most of public procuring entities (Alford and Hughes, 2008; Dean, 2015). Due to insufficient explanations on increasing effect of transaction costs in competitive tendering prevailing situations require scientific enquiry, therefore present study seeks to explore the moderation effect of integrity on transaction costs in competitive tendering.

 

Problem formulation

 

It is self-evident that the current economic crisis places a premium on governments cutting spending and increasing savings. With public procurement typically accounting for 10 to 20% of a country's GDP and 65 to 70% of public sector budgets, governments face the challenge of maximizing value while rigorously reducing government spending. On the other hand, while the call for a more cohesive interface between the public and private sectors is currently resonating, public procurement has been plagued by scandals, mismanagement, and possibly corruption (Lodhia and Burritt, 2004; Beth, 2007). As a result, competitive public procurement creates numerous opportunities for both public and private actors to divert public funds for private gain (Adusei and Awunyo-Vitor, 2015; Akaninyene and Mark, 2015).

 

This demonstrates a lack of integrity, as the majority of government entities' spending is vulnerable to providing fewer services with increased spending.

 

The present study seeks to explore the linkages between transaction costs, integrity and competitive tendering. Its primary goal is to investigate impact of behavioural dimensions of transaction costs that were scantly investigated in the field of public procurement before – opportunism and bounded rationality. Main attempt is to find a more comprehensive understanding of the relationship between these transaction costs dimensions and competitive tendering and integrity. Its secondary goal is to establish whether integrity plays a mediating role between competitive tendering and transaction costs. Consensus on the importance of affect does not preclude differences, and there is a lively debate concerning the direction of mediation on integrity between transaction costs and competitive tendering as well as the determining nature and relative influence of various individual behaviours when obtaining public requirements.

 

Integrity translates into the degree to which public procurement practitioners are trustworthy, as bidders and other stakeholders require assurance that they can rely on any information distributed by the procurement entity, whether formally or informally (Bovis, 2006; Hunja, 2003; Beth, 2007; Khan, 2018). Many have identified the problems associated with competitive tendering and its implications for public sector procurement as not only enormous but also complex, and there is a pressing need on the part of various government servants to improve service quality while maintaining integrity. This means that integrity is critical at all stages of the public procurement process.

Literatures have noticed that integrity in business practices acts as hidden hand of social forces often beyond individuals’ behavioural control and guides transactional practices (Somera and Holt, 2015; Banks, 2004). The issues surrounding competitive tendering and its implications for public sector procurement have been identified by many as not only enormous but also complex, particularly in light of the pressing need for various government servants to provide substandard services on a shoestring budget.

 

Thus, in public procurement terms, integrity is critical at all levels. This study is endeavor to reach a more comprehensive understanding of the relationship between transaction costs dimensions on competitive tendering with a special focus on behavioural aspects in public sector. Its secondary goal is to establish whether integrity plays a moderating role between competitive tendering and transaction costs. Consensus on the importance of affect does not preclude differences, and there is a lively debate concerning the direction of relationships between transaction costs dimensions, integrity and competitive tendering as well as the nature and relative influence of various public procurement practitioners’ behaviours when obtaining public requirements.


 LITERATURE REVIEW AND HYPOTHESIS DEVELOPMENT

Effect of bounded rationality on competitive tendering

 

Tendering is a procurement procedure whereby potential bidders are invited to make a firm and unequivocal offer on the price and non-price terms which on acceptance shall be the basis of a subsequent contract (Lysons and Farrington, 2006; Beth, 2007). The aim of using competitive tendering is to reduce costs and improve the efficiency across multiple decisional dimensions (Ayoti, 2012; Rivasplata, 2002). The process of rational decision making in competitive tendering favours logic, objectivity, and analysis over subjectivity and insight. In public procurement, rational model of decision making assumes that individuals will make choices that maximize benefits and minimise any costs in competitive tendering (Uzonwanne, 2016; Hansson and Holmgren, 2011). Moreover, it is likely that the decision connections will never be entirely specified because humans are complex beings, as are the organisations and social systems they inhabit (Jones, 2017; Bennet and Bennet, 2008). As a consequence decisional linkages in competitive tendering process are likely to be incomplete.

 

In theory, public procurement process comprises of individuals who are highly organised and thorough rational-comprehensive idealists involving systematically evaluation and ranking of a wide range of alternatives before choosing the best alternatives based on decisional criteria (Uzonwanne, 2016; Hansson and Holmgren, 2011).

Consequently, procurement processes requires sound reasoning to cater for well-informed decisions with successful strategies (Steane and Walker, 2000; Rivasplata, 2002). However in practice, decisions are often based on a much more limited range of information and analysis (Tukuta and Saruchera, 2015; Testa, et al., 2016). Thus, under bounded conditions a rational model for competitive tendering is minimal workable in complex situations when bounded by imperfect information, limited intellectual capacities, and a value problem (Gigerenzer and Selten, 2002; Lunenburg, 2010). Thus, in this study it is predicted that:

 

H1: Bounded rationality will have positive effect on competitive tendering.

 

Effect of opportunism on competitive tendering

 

Opportunism is the conscious policy and practice of taking advantage of circumstances – with little regard for principles, or with what the consequences are for others. Opportunism negatively impacts relational exchange tenets in public procurement such as trust, compliance, professional values and ethics. It is manifested in behaviours such as stealing, cheating, dishonesty, and withholding information. Opportunist actions are expedient actions guided primarily by self-interested motives.

However in typical entrepreneurial action, opportunism is about taking advantage of the prevailing situation or circumstances. It involves a degree of flexibility in exploring and taking advantage of the opportunities such as tendering, that situations and circumstances provide profits and strengthen the business. Planned opportunism in real life requires sensitivity to “weak signals,” which offers to early evidence of emerging trends from which it is possible to deduce important economic opportunities. There is a need of comprehensive examination necessary in order to understand why procurement practitioners engage in acts of opportunism in competitive tendering. Appreciation on why opportunism in competitive tendering occurs will reveal how to deter it, and this remains a gap in the literature. On the basis of previous studies it is hypothesized that:

 

H2: Opportunism will positively affect the competitive tendering.

 

Relationship between Integrity and competitive tendering

 

On one hand, integrity can  have  impact  on  transaction costs, but, on the other hand, transaction costs also have influence on the type and depth of integrity. The ontological law of integrity portrays the degree that integrity is diminished; the opportunity for performance (the opportunity set) is diminished. This means performance in public procurement transactions such as competitive tendering is easily compromised by ethical dilemma, improper inducement, fear of retaliation, clientlism and administrative secrecy. There seems to be evidence that a higher incidence of adverse events is associated with higher transaction costs (Lingard et al., 1998; Ho and Tsui, 2009).

 

However, it is agreed that, to build up integrity in competitive tendering, as an investment in transaction costs is necessary. Particularly, in a procurement cycle, interactions between transacting parties in one phase will impact or even determine the next phase of the transaction. Irrespective of the context, the list of integrity indicators that represent areas of activity in the contracting process that fail on integrity is extremely damaging in terms of the weak administrative controls (Tan, 2013), incapability of policy instruments (Georghiou et al., 2014) and improper use of official power (Gaziano, 2000).

 

Integrity plays two roles in transactions: firstly, through norms and sanctions, integrity may act as a substitute for the formal control system in governing transactions. Secondly, there is evidence that integrity can facilitate the formation of ongoing networks governing economic transactions. Therefore, further review of literature from this research confirm that ethical dilemma (Awuor and Muthoni, 2014), improper inducement (Williams and Quinot, 2007), fear of retaliation (Williams-Elegbe, 2015), clientlism (Osei-Afoakwa, 2012) and administrative secrecy can not only deter formal control system but also formation of ongoing networks governing economic transactions in competitive tendering. Therefore, it is predicted that:

 

H3: There will be a positive relationship between integrity and competitive tendering.

 

Linking moderation effect of integrity with opportunism in competitive tendering

 

Integrity is a concept of consistency of actions, values, methods, measures, principles, expectations, and outcomes (Karthikeyan, 2017). According to OECD (2009) a “negative” approach to define integrity is also useful to determine an effective strategy for preventing integrity violations’ in the field of public procurement. In ethics, integrity is regarded as the honesty and truthfulness or accuracy of one’s actions. In this paper, integrity can be defined as the condition that occurs when persons adhere to accepted standards, professional   values,   and   practices    of     the    public procurement community (Udechukwu, 2007; Tukuta and Saruchera, 2015). And consistency of actions and adherence to integrity standards ensures avoidance of anomalies, fraud, and misappropriation of public funds or instances of corruption and helps prevent conflict of interest, collusion, abuse and manipulation of information, inequality, waste and abuse of public resources (Tremblay, 2017; Moorman and Grover, 2009).

 

Empirical evidence from the literatures exploring the relationship between integrity and performance of competitive tendering emphasizes importance of effective strategy for preventing integrity violations’ in the field of public procurement. In overall, higher integrity is associated with higher level of competitive tendering performance. And this call, public procurement practitioners must display personal and professional integrity in competitive tendering (OECD, 2009; Dimitri et al., 2006). When reflecting individual level in public procurement, integrity is more than ethics, it is all about the innate characteristics of an individual (Dunn, 2009; Haack, 2007).  In actual facts, integrity is a concept that displays a consistency between actions and values or principles.

 

The Turknett leadership group notes that individuals of integrity will not twist facts for personal advantage; they are willing to stand up for and defend what is right; they will be careful to keep promises; and they can be counted on to tell the truth. Whereas, a professional is one who willingly "adopts" and consistently applies the public procurement knowledge, skills, and values in accordance with social standards or moral values. Thus, professional integrity thus defines the professional who consistently and willingly practices within the public procurement ethical standards.

 

According to Barnard, et al., (2008), there are several factors that support and strengthen the integrity: self-motivation and drive, moral courage and assertiveness, honesty, consistency, commitment, diligence, self-discipline, responsibility, trustworthiness, and fairness.

 

These factors acts as incentives resulting in higher competitive tendering performance and hence reduces opportunistic behaviour.  Different authors produce empirical evidence that in public procurement absence of integrity enables integrity violations at a higher rate.

 

Competitive tendering is often considered to promote competition, provide transparency and give all bidders the opportunity to convey value for money (Ackah et al., 2014; Erridge and McIlroy, 2002). But in some cases opportunism tends to erode trust, and without trust public procurement practitioners are much less likely to continually improving savings –and continually reducing cost in competitive tendering (Ozkan-Tektas, 2014; Huo et al., 2015). Integrity in transaction represent fair and unbiased treatment but partner opportunism goes against the development of mutual trust and the cooperative spirit, accentuating the perception of risk and   jeopardizing   the   interfirm  relationship  (Das  and Teng, 2001, 2004).

 

Specifically, integrity represent areas of activity in procurement process comprises of behavioural perspectives necessary for achieving transactional objectives (Heggstad et al., 2010; Akaninyene and Mark, 2015). Usually, decision to effect competitive tendering is a symmetrical process, where the two actors assess procurement situation through information exchange, exploration of mutual needs, definition of content, planning of implementation, and expectation and evaluation of outcomes: efficiency, satisfaction and performance (Mayavi, 2013; Reeves, 2008).

 

Presence of opportunism can directly affect to a quick and unexpected increase of transaction cost and curtail the competitive tendering performance because parties must engage in legal contacts as a safeguard against opportunism (Ping Ho et al., 2015; Hawkins, 2007).

Thus, opportunism in competitive tendering mainly denotes an imperfect or distorted expose of information, that it would generate mistrusts and limit competition, transparency and value for money in competitive tendering and interrupts the outcomes of exchange relationships (Tadelis and Bajari, 2006; Mantzaris, 2014). This means, participants of competitive tendering having the highest transaction cost are primarily related to absence of integrity (Erridge et al., 1999; Agerberg and Ågren, 2012). If opportunism exists in competitive tendering, the procurement transactions cannot be organized efficiently (Hobbs, 1996; Ackah et al., 2014) and one partner can take advantage of the other, so that victim's partner needs high costs to find and evaluate obtained information (Priyanath and Buthsala, 2017).  Therefore, this study proposes the fourth hypothesis in a new context that:

 

H4: Integrity will moderate the effect of opportunism on competitive tendering positively.

 

Linking moderation effect of integrity with bounded rationality and competitive tendering

 

The transactional approach considers competitive tendering as the unit of economic analysis and explains the evolution of relationships in competitive tendering as transactions and contracts (Moronda, 2014; Rivasplata, 2002).

 

Transaction costs analysis highlights the relevance of institutions in procurement markets when characterized by bounded rationality on the part of the procurement practitioners (Seeletse and Ladzani, 2012; Baltos et al., 2018).

 

Related to this, institutional structure of public procurement acts as a set of rules that determines the individual incentives, volume of transaction costs, and biasness in competitive tendering output (Oluka, 2013; Mwandobo, 2013).

 

In this manner, institutional and individual structures can be analyzed, and one of their main function is focused on economizing transaction costs.

 

Whereby rational economic approach thinks individually, procurement practitioner seeks to maximise utility from limited income derived from rational choice. Rationality in the real world is a complex concept because individuals calculate optimal solutions for every decision and bounded by the lack of knowledge (Gigerenzer and Selten, 2002; Yang et al., 2015). And since the capacity of the human mind to formulate and solve complex problems is very small compared to the size of the problems, whose solution is necessary for objectively rational behaviour in the real world, rationality becomes bounded rationality (Hernández and Ortega, 2019; Valéro, 2015). Thus, according to Shannon et al. (2019) bounded rationality conceives of individuals engaging in competitive tendering as goal oriented but endowed with cognitive and emotional architectures that limit their abilities to pursue those goals rationally. From above explanations, it is understood that in the tensions that exist between institutions and individual, there is a great demand to compete based on incomplete information within the individual conscience.

 

Individuals in competitive tendering don’t utilise ideal decision-making approaches as a result of cognitive limitations in the capacity to understand and oversee complex information as a consequence of difficulties related with impediments in information accessibility (Alam and Pacher, 2000; Mathisen and Solvoll, 2008). This means individuals in competitive tendering are faced with time constraints, restricted access to information, and with ‘cognitive limitations’ cannot solve problems optimally, but take short-cuts by employing public procurement rules to save on mental processing time and energy (Gelderman et al., 2006; Ngugi and Mugo, 2012). 

 

The reasons that explain the high level of transaction costs in competitive tendering exchange and organisation are the following: firstly, in competitive tendering contracts, situations of VFM are particularly relevant in competitive tendering transactions and furthermore, the unacceptable contract delays and manipulation of contract awards increase different perspectives proffer conflicting opinions on integrity attainment; secondly, in public procurement there are numerous actors and stakeholders involved in a complex decision-making environment with more complex transaction characteristics will require integrity to make them effective over time. The problem of effective competition characterizes a wide range of competitive tendering transactions; thirdly, the ineffective competition leads to a lower efficiency and a less intense economic provider, such that the relationship between effort and effect becomes quite unclear and competition problems are augmented; and fourthly, the world of public procurement is complex, opaque and it is difficult to observe and measure the different  factors  of transparency, for example the measure of objects of competitive tendering transaction is really complex and partially subjective.

 

In order to effectively identify participate in competitive tendering, bidders need as much information as possible (Ackah et al., 2014; Raymond, 2008). A tender that has little to no information on description of requirements can be disqualified as irresponsive, thus providing a clear advantage to the incumbent and anyone else with knowledge of the tender (Erridge and McIlroy, 2002; Cabras, 2011). The asymmetry information together with opportunistic behaviour of any participant in competitive tendering generates not only moral hazard but also adverse selection (Schieg, 2008; Bergh et al., 2019). Henceforth, there is a correlation between competitive tendering in public procurement and bounded rationality as well as broader, positive procurement outcomes (Thai, 2001; Agaba and Shipman, 2007).

 

For a procurement practitioner to be procedurally rational, it is necessary that procurement decisions result from an appropriate process of deliberation are free to vary according to perceived knowledge and information. In this way bounded rationality form the basis of a potential reason which makes some procurement practitioners to violate favourable integrity decisions when applying competitive tendering. However, presence of tensions between institutions and individual, to compete to compete based on incomplete information within the individual conscience exacerbate conflicting perspectives on conductance of competitive tendering. Therefore, it is proposed that:

 

H5: Integrity will moderate the effect of bounded rationality on competitive tendering positively.

 

A hypothetical model, as exhibited in Figure 1, has been developed considering the above literature and hypotheses.

 

Figure 1 exhibits the integrity moderating model for linking transaction costs and competitive tendering which constitutes the conceptual framework of this study. The conceptual framework of this study includes the impact of moderating effect of integrity to bounded rationality and opportunism on competitive tendering as described earlier.


 METHODOLOGY

Design and sample

 

This study used a non-experimental, predictive survey design. A random sample of 298 respondents working in public procurement in Dodoma was selected. Inclusion criteria incorporated respondents employed public and private sector who are involved in public procurement and specifically on competitive tendering. Of the 298 questionnaires, 174 were sent to public procurement practitioners who were identified as public officials, either through information obtained from the PPRA or by contacting and asking someone associated with the Procuring Entity (usually the Accounting Officer). A final sample of 220 completed and useable surveys was obtained for a 73.8% response rate. A sample size of at least 200 participants is recommended as sufficient for structural equation modeling (Hu and Bentler, 1995; Kline 2005).

 

 

Data collection methods

 

This kind of data analysis involves probing of data collected through semi-structured interviews. The survey focuses on the public procurement officials and private sector practitioners who are procuring goods, services and works from public sector. The variables selected in this study are integrity, transaction costs and competitive tendering. Items selected to measure these variables were adopted from previous studies. All the variables were measured using five point likert scale with level 1= strongly disagree and 5=strongly agree.

 

Measures

 

Competitive tendering

 

Put simply, competitive tendering is a formal process which results in an “offer” made by a supplier, contractor or consultant in response to an invitation to tender (Brook, 2016; Smith, 2017). Suppliers, contractors or consultants tendering for goods, works or services are often competing amongst themselves and are encouraged to submit most competitive tender.

 

Competitive tendering should adopt and observe the key values of fairness, transparency, competitive, while ensuring value for money, as well as reinforce the idea of apportionment of risk to the party best placed to assess and manage for the success of public procurement (Brook, 2016; Kang et al., 2018). In competitive tendering transactions and decisions must in all respects be transparency, competitive, and ensure value for money (Ackah et al., 2014; Erridge and McIlroy, 2002). Thus, contracting entities and individuals when participating in competitive tendering are required to justify decisions made and actions taken. Measurements of competitive tendering in this study included the following indicators:

 

(1) Transparency in public procurement means that information on the public procurement process must be available  to everyone: contractors, suppliers, service providers and the public at large (Lynch and Angel, 2013). Transparency needs to pervade in all steps in of procurement cycle. Transparency in competitive tendering enables processes and decisions to be monitored and reviewed, helps ensure that decision-makers can be held accountable and also helps open public procurement to more competition (Wang and Rosenau, 2001; Raymond, 2008). According to Jeppesen (2010) and Thai, 2017) there is little doubt that under the right circumstances increased transparency in public procurement can lead to greater accountability, better service delivery and, ultimately, less waste of public resources. With the adoption of transparency in competitive tendering the suppliers, contractors or consultants benefits from a level playing field, predictable business environments and a reduction in risk.

 (2) Value for money is the core principle underpinning public procurement. Asare and Prempeh (2016) posited that value for money refers to the optimum combination of “whole life cost” and “quality” to meet the customer or the end-users requirement of the procured goods or service under consideration and usually reflected in the price of the item procured. In most cases value for money is not about achieving the lowest price; it is about achieving the optimum combination of whole life costs and quality (World Bank, 2003). In competitive tendering, principle of value for money requires a comparative analysis of all relevant costs and benefits of each proposal throughout the whole procurement cycle (whole-of-life costing). Basically, Manu (2005) asserted that, value for money is enhanced in public procurement by: encouraging competition by ensuring non-discrimination in procurement and using competitive procurement processes; promoting the use of resources in an efficient, effective and ethical manner; and making decisions in an accountable and transparent manner.

 

The Victorian Government (2019) viewed that value for money is the achievement of a desired procurement outcome at the best possible price - not necessarily the lowest price - based on a balanced judgment of financial and non-financial factors relevant to the procurement. In order to be in the best position in determining value for money when conducting a procurement process, request documentation needs to specify logical, clearly articulated, comprehensive and relevant conditions for participation and evaluation criteria which will enable the proper identification, assessment and comparison of the costs and benefits of all submissions on a fair and common basis over the whole procurement cycle that is fit for purpose and meets specification. Assessment of bids should be conducted in relation to a published

set of evaluation criteria, which must be relevant to the subject matter of the contract, and any added value that justifies a higher price must flow from these defined criteria (Office of Government,

2007).

 

At the heart of the concept of value for money, are three critical elements namely economy, efficiency and effectiveness. This is often described in terms of the ‘three Es’:

 

Economy: Explores whether specific inputs are acquired at the lowest cost and at the right time (doing things at a low price at the right time).

 

Efficiency: This refers to how productively inputs are translated into outputs. It further means that there should be maximum output with little cost (doing things the right way with reasonable effort).

 

Effectiveness: The extent to which outputs achieve the desired outcomes (doing the right things to meet procurement objectives).

 

3) Competition between bidders provides the means for ensuring that public entities, and ultimately society as a whole, obtain the benefit of the best offers in terms of price, quality and innovation of the goods and services eventually purchased (Sanchez-Graells, 2011). According to Guide on Public Procurement and Competition (2011) most procurement arrangements are set up through a mechanism that lies between the extremes of buying in an open market and negotiating a specific contract. Promoting competitive practices and adopting measures to mitigate corruption, seems to be the most plausible solution to enhance efficiency in the public procurement process of competitive tendering (Søreide, 2002; Achua, 2011; Valéro, 2015). The basic idea behind this principle is that competition leads to reasonable price, quality and is good for the economy; consequently, the public procurement process should not be manipulated to give preference to any particular firm(s) or individual(s).

 

Competition concerns arising from public procurement are largely at the need to tackle anticompetitive practices and avoidance of publicly-created distortions of competition as a result of the exercise of buying power by the public sector, or the creation of regulatory barriers to access public procurement markets (Graells, 2016; Broms et al., 2019).

 

Competitive tendering has very clear common value elements as cost of providing a particular service is very often identical or very similar for all participants (Ackah et al., 2014; Lynch and Angel, 2013). A rule of thumb is that more bidders make for more intense competition, resulting in lower prices and better quality. However, anti-competitive practices such as quoting equal prices and discounts, the rotation of lowest tenderer and contract sharing undermine competition by discouraging the participation of potential bidders and reduce cost savings through inflating tender prices (Qaqaya and Lipimile, 2008; Singh and Dhumale, 2001).

 

Transaction costs                  

 

Transaction costs, these are economic losses that can result from arranging market relationships on a contractual violated by different parties when they find an opportunity thus limiting the authority of contractual relationships. In this study, a transaction cost is a cost incurred in making an economic exchange of goods, works or services, or in other words the cost of participating in a procurement transaction. The level of transaction cost depends on certain institution within procurement structures and system of organising a transaction (Rajeh and Rotimi, 2013; Nikolaeva and Pletnev, 2016). Transaction costs have becomes a category of importance because of steadily increasing opportunistic behaviour and bounded rationality in procurement contractual arrangements (Mroczek-D?browska and Gorynia, 2019;  Hennart,  2010;  Valéro, 2015).

 

Transaction cost economics seeks to explain why some bids in competitive tendering have many participants and why there are some bids dominated by just a few large suppliers, contractors or service providers (Dowall and Whittington, 2008; Hennart, 2010). Transaction cost suggests that profits and savings in competitive tendering are partly explained by the desire to reduce transaction costs from the market mechanism and concentrate productivity within a transacting firm though human behaviour (Rajeh et al., 2013; Todorova, 2016).

 

Most of the researchers on transaction costs have indicated how stakeholders are faced with challenges due to the costs incurred during transaction by both parties, these leads to higher cost of procurement, less economic efficiency in the procurement chain system (Yahaya et al., 2019; Jonah, 2018). Essentially, transaction cost as noted by Priyanto et al., 2014) is paid by exchange parties in a non-perfect information stated condition, which participated by opportunistic behaved actors, and providing bounded rationality. This portrays, transaction cost theory has often been used to support the idea that opportunism and bounded rationality can increase imperfection in the economic system (ibid). However, integrity has repeatedly been described as solutions to inefficiencies in the organisation of transactions in complex and uncertain settings (Cordelia, 2006; Somera and Holt, 2015). 

 

Transaction costs scholars have long recognized that transaction costs are strongly influenced by the characteristics of a transaction such as its degree of bounded rationality and opportunism (Dorward, 2001; Rajeh et al., 2013).

 

According to Carr et al. (2007), Transaction costs are incurred through the processes of information searches required to make decisions, along with those of negotiating, monitoring, and enforcing agreements. The existence of bounded rationality and opportunism create confusion among suppliers, service providers and contractors as to what they are paying for, leading to increased distrust of the competitive tendering, rather than fostering greater trust and confidence (Thomassen et al., 2016; Augier, 2016; Gigerenzer and Selten, 2002). This means, in competitive tendering, transaction costs will limit potential savings from public tendering because of problems associated with bounded rationality and opportunism (Thomassen et al., 2016; Parker and Hartley, 2003).

 

According to the transaction costs economy (TCE) literature, the problem of economic organization entails the planning of governance structures that have the purpose and effect of economizing on bounded rationality while safeguarding transactions against the threat of opportunism. In this study, we are interested in understanding buyer behavior by drawing on the main notion of behavioral decision-making, and in particular bounded rationality (Simon, 1947) and the related concept of opportunism (Hodgson, 2004). Measures of transaction costs in this study included the following indicators:

 

Opportunism

 

Opportunism as defined by Williamson (1975) is the lack of candor or honesty in transactions, to include self-interest seeking with guile. In this study opportunistic behaviour is the use of incomplete or distorted disclosure of information especially to calculated efforts to mislead, distort, disguise, obfuscate or otherwise confuse participants of competitive tendering. The aim of opportunism is to realize the individual advantage while disregarding the interests of others (Hodgson, 2004; Furrer et al., 2013). In opportunism, the participants in competitive tendering will try to lower their trust thus failing to fulfill promises or obligations (Tyler, 2001; Merry et al., 2012).

 

In competitive tendering, opportunism is the practice of taking advantage  of  circumstances –  with  little  regard  for  principles or with what the consequences are for others (Önder and Erdil, 2017; Kauppi and Van Raaij, 2015; Valéro, 2015). Usually, opportunist actions are expedient actions guided primarily by self-interested motives. Explanations of opportunistic behavior (both for and against) typically focus on the proclivity of exchange partners to engage in deceptive and self-serving behavior (John, 1984; Hill, 1990; Williamson, 1985). Any contractual relationship in competitive tendering usually involves both cooperation between the contracting partners, so that each gets what they want from others, and competition by each party to get the best deal for themselves. So the contractual relationship is normally both self-directed towards avoidance of selfishness and self-interest.

 

Threat of opportunism is defined as lack of integrity that a public procurement practitioner will cause unfairness and thereby failing to fulfill procurement promises or obligations. Perceptions of unfairness in the distribution of savings and accrued benefits will increase transaction costs because procurement negotiation will shift to false promises and misrepresenting intentions (Rajeh et al., 2013; Petrovic and Milos, 2011). However, in within competitive tendering settings, many transactions involve multiple decision makers to both sides of transactions. These decision makers include both upper level management as well as lower level operational and technical personnel (Argyres and Mayer, 2007). The main challenge in competitive tendering is how to determine, negotiate, and manage an appropriate governance mode on added complexity in multi-level settings of decision makers manifested by selfishness and self-interest (Ackah et al., 2014; Steane and Walker, 2000).

 

Bounded rationality

 

Bounded rationality, in this study is a notion that portraits the limitations of rational thinking in decision making processes in competitive tendering. Boundedly rational decision making involves non-optimising procedures coupled with inability and unwillingness to follow a reasoned, unemotional and logical approach in decision making (Foss, 2003; Puranam et al., 2015). Usually, public procurement decisions are a kind of decisions and represent a conscious choice, a voluntary act, the final result of deliberation, a decision maker activities, with as object of activity public business. However, capacity of human knowledge is limited, whereby – its collection, storage, organisation and application involves costs and time – and this naturally limits the scope for perfect choices of options by individuals (Holtz, 2005; Ishak et al., 2010).

 

In most cases, possibility for exchange with other individuals extends the range of options available to individuals. While this increased range of options could further limit an individual’s capacity to optimise (places more bounds on perfect rationality), there is also a possibility of opposite recurrence. For example, individuals in competitive tendering may specialise in knowledge-related activities and some social mechanisms, such as the price mechanism, may reduce the need for gathering of information.

 

Bounded rationality is the idea of making decisions that are rational, but within the limits of the information available to procurement practitioners’ mental capabilities. It was noted that capacity of human beings is limited in relation to knowledge and information which naturally limits the scope for perfect choices when applying competitive tendering in public procurement. The possibility for exchange extends the range of options available to procurement practitioners in competitive tendering. While this increased range of options could further limit procurement practitioners’ capacity to optimise thus greater possibility of performing opposite decisions.

 

For a procurement practitioner to be procedurally rational, it is necessary that procurement decisions result from an appropriate process of deliberation are free to vary according to perceived knowledge and information. In this way bounded rationality form the basis of a potential reason which makes some procurement practitioners to violate favourable integrity decisions when applying competitive tendering. On the basis of previous studies it is hypnotized that:

 

Integrity

 

Integrity in this study can be asserted as unwavering consistency and persistence to uphold professional values and beliefs. Simply put, integrity is a concept that shows a consistency between actions and values (Rohr, 2008; Tomlinson et al., 2014). Usually, public procurement practitioners involved in the competitive tendering should, at all times, be perceived as honest, trustworthy, responsible and reliable (Kiage, 2013; Caldwell et al., 2005; Handfield, 2014).

 

Therefore, public practitioners must always keep the rationale of procurement requirement in mind, and strive to ensure they responsibly manage competitive tendering as mandated by the public procurement rules and regulations.

Measurement of the integrity in competitive tendering in this study includes indicators are as follows:

 

1) Trust is a belief that someone is honest and credible; trust is earned by being honest, having a positive intent, having strong competencies, and a track record of results (Kruse, 2019). In this instance, procurement practitioner must find a way to balance competitive tendering objectives and goals against their end users’ needs, while also maintaining trust and credibility in the eyes of the end user.

2) Compliance is a complex responsibility requiring measurement and reporting against a dynamic and seemingly endless array of rules, agreements, standards, regulations, and legislation (Gebler, 2006).  In general, compliance is the process of making sure procurement practitioners follow all laws, regulations, standards, and ethical practices that apply to competitive tendering.

 3) Ethics in procurement ethics represent collection of moral principles or a set of values dealing with what is right or wrong, good or bad in business transactions (Vallario, 2007; Lager, 2009). Such sets of values are being shared within the business community as well as the society as a whole. Moral ideas are considered to be inappropriate for everyday business dealings and some actions are disregarded due to the strong desire to make profit.

4) Professional values are the principles that guide public procurement practitioner’s decisions and actions in career (Roman, 2017; Tabish and Jha, 2011). While those with a strong values system and ethical standards of the highest degree are easily recognizable by their deeds and are intrinsically motivated to do the right thing even when no one is watching. Professional values indicate business-related beliefs or principles that guide professional behaviour (Poorchangizi et al., 2019; Tabish and Jha, 2011). Values may reflect ethics, practices, standards and other norms within a commercial environment.

5) Honesty may be seen as transparency and openness. Honesty in public procurement promotes openness, empowers and enables procurement practitioners to develop consistency behaviour on how to present facts when conducting competitive tendering (Wittig and Jeng, 2005; Kaspar and Puddephatt, 2012).  Being honesty implies a refusal to lie, steal, or deceive in any way while adhering to a code of moral values (Kauppi and Van Raaij, 2015; Valéro, 2015). In that manner, honesty involves behaviour of straight forwardness, trustworthiness, loyal, fair, and sincere. Honesty is the literal opposite of dishonesty, and the antonyms such as lying, cheating, theft and insincerity along with criminal-specific traits.

Despite the importance of public procurement, the number of studies  that  investigate  the  role of public authorities in integrity is still small. Conversely, this may result in gains from public procurement transactions by exploiting a client’s integrity and extracting increased economic value from transactions through higher pricing. It is very important that the public procurement function is discharged honestly, trustfulness, and in a manner that secures efficiency in competitive tendering. This means, quality of the outcomes is fundamental in understanding whether integrity is providing value in the competitive tendering in the presence of opportunism and bounded rationality in public procurement.


 RESULTS

Data normality assumptions

 

Before running the regression models and testing the study hypothesis, Kolmogorov-Smirnov test for data normality was applied. The results for the numeric variables show that the data is normal for all the variables at a significance level of 0.05. An inspection of the bi-variate coefficients for the dimensions of integrity, transaction costs and competitive tendering in the correlation matrix reveals that these are well less than unity (range 0.428-0.649) and therefore, not linearly dependent; this simple measure rules out the chances of muticollinearity (Montgomery et al., 2009). It can also be observed from Table 2 that the values of correlation coefficients of study dimensions are less than 0.85 which also provides the evidence of discriminant validity (Hoang et al., 2006; Kline, 2005) and confirm that the problem of multicollinearity does not exist amongst the study dimensions of integrity, TCs and competitive tendering (Jun et al., 2006; Sit et al., 2009). This may be mentioned here that being dimensions of the same construct, these are supposed to be correlated; accordingly the bi-variate correlations among the study dimensions are well above zero.

 

Confirmatory factor analysis

 

Prior to hypotheses testing, exploration on whether the three strategies could be distinguished empirically was performed. On that fact, confirmatory factor analyses (CFA) was conducted using the AMOS software package (Arbuckle, 2007) and the maximum likelihood method. The factor model which included each strategy as latent factors, which were indicated by specified items. The latent factors were allowed to correlate. The model suitability for both scales was assessed, and the findings revealed suitable parameters for all indicators: GFI = 0.954, AGFI = 0.932, CFI = 0.959, RMSEA = 0.627, chi-square/df = 3.891 and TLI=0.801. However, all items loaded significantly on the intended latent factors. Modification indexes showed that no cross-loadings were suggested; some correlations between the disturbances were suggested. The convergent and divergent validity of scores on both scales provided evidence in the expected direction.

 

In this study, confirmatory factor analysis (CFA) is used to test the reliability of unidimensional and indicator was conducted so as to observe value of construct validity. Either, testing the significance of loading critical ratio, if the value of the critical ratio is greater than the critical value at the 0.05 level of significance (critical values = 1.96) then the indicators significantly is an indicator of construct validity formed (Ghozali, 2005). Evaluation of reliability construct uses the value of level of reliability which is 0.7 (Ferdinand, 2006). Table 1 shows the test results are constructs reliability unidimensional and show proof of reliability is good.

 

Table 1 displays the mean scores, standard deviations, and correlations among the study variables. As can be seen in Table 1, opportunism has a significant and positive correlation with competitive tendering (0.458, p<0.01). Similarly, bounded rationality was found to be notably correlated to competitive tendering (0.702, p<0.01). Integrity also shows a strong level of association with competitive tendering (0.970, p<0.01). Thus it can be observed that there is initial support for all of study variables.

 

Hypothesis testing and hierarchical regression analysis

 

To test the moderation and the main effect of the study variable, the hierarchical regression analysis was used. The results achieved through the analysis are shown in Table 2. The results indicate that opportunism has a negative but significant effect on competitive tendering (β = 0.037, p<0.001), therefore Hypothesis 1 is accepted. The relationship of bounded rationality with competitive tendering was found to be significant (β = 0.077, p<0.001), hence hypothesis 2 is accepted. Results further indicated that integrity has a significant and positive effect on competitive tendering (β = 0.904, p<0.001), therefore hypothesis 3 is accepted. The results of moderated regression analysis show that integrity moderate the relation of opportunism and competitive tendering (β = 0.002, p<0.001), in consequence hypothesis 4 is accepted. The moderation outcome of integrity on the relationship of bounded rationality and competitive tendering was found to be significant (β = -0.072, p<0.001) therefore hypothesis 5 is also accepted.

 

Hypothesis 1 predicted that bounded rationality will have positive effect on competitive tendering. Multiple regression analysis testing a main effects model yielded a significant and negative regression of bounded rationality on competitive tendering (β = -0.352, p < 0.001), and consequently not supported. Hypothesis 2 predicted that opportunism will positively affect the competitive tendering. As shown in Basic model 1 (Table 2), multiple regression analysis testing a main effects model shows significant and negative regression of bounded rationality on competitive tendering (β = -0.521, p  <  0.001)   and  consequently  not  supported.  Results further indicated that integrity has a significant and positive effect on competitive tendering (β = 0.952, p<0.001), therefore hypothesis 3 is accepted. Hypothesis 4 predicted that integrity will moderate the effect of opportunism on competitive tendering positively and, and Hypothesis 5 stated that integrity will moderate the effect of bounded rationality on competitive tendering positively. Thus, Hypotheses 4 and 5 are supported. As shown in model 3 (Table 2), a significant interaction exists between bounded rationality on competitive tendering (β = -0.294, p < 0.001), and the explained variance in the model is due to main effects (??2 = 0.04, p < 0.001). Similarly, the interaction of integrity with opportunism and competitive tendering shown in model 3 (Table 2) is significant and positive (β = -0.15, p < 0.01), and the explained variance in the model is due to effects beyond those due to main effects (??2 = 0.02, p < 0.01). For the measure of integrity, the results of hierarchical regression yielded a greater effect of bounded rationality variables (Step 2) [B=-0.882, R2=0.372, ΔR2=0.732].

 

Entering the effects of each integrity dimension into the regression equation (Step 2) yielded a significant increase in the explained variance [F = 11.50, p<0.0001, ΔR2=0.33] with a high efficiency of competitive tendering (β=0.782, p<0.001), a small contribution of BR (β=0.15, p=0.053). An identical pattern of results was obtained for opportunism and competitive tendering (Table 2). The effect of integrity variables (Step 1) were greater (ΔR2=0.12 on the presence of opportunism. The introduction of integrity (Step 3) yielded a significant increase in the explained variance (ΔR2=0.649), with a high contribution of competitive tendering and reduction of opportunism (β=0.14, p=0.058).

 

 


 DISCUSSION

In this study, it was found that, the support from the previous literature from presented results that bounded rationality has a considerably negative effect on competitive tendering. This is in line with the study of Foss (2003) and Puranam et al. (2015) who observed that bounded rationality involves non-optimising procedures coupled with inability and unwillingness to follow a reasoned, unemotional and logical approach in decision making process. Similarly Holtz (2005), and Ishak et al. (2010) observed that capacity of human knowledge is limited, whereby – its collection, storage, organisation and application involves costs and time – and this naturally limits the scope for perfect choices of options by individuals. Results signified that opportunism has a significant effect on competitive tendering which is same as hypothesized. The authors found support for our findings from Rajeh et al. (2013), Petrovic and Milos (2011) study who found that perceptions of unfairness in the distribution of savings and accrued benefits will increase transaction costs because procurement negotiation will shift to false promises and mis-representing intentions. Studies of Ackah, et al., (2014), Steane and Walker (2000) found that the main challenge in competitive tendering is how to determine, negotiate, and manage an appropriate governance mode on added complexity in multi-level settings of decision makers manifested by selfishness and self-interest.

 

From the statistical data analysis it was observed that practitioner’s level of integrity has significant negative effect on competitive tendering. It is also found that integrity guides practitioners to attain procurement goals and can construct immoral friendly relationship among participants in procurement process (Lynch and Angel, 2013; Darabad, 2017). In this paper, integrity is found by five factors which are trust, compliance, ethics professional values, and honesty. Poor integrity in public procurement can be a source of negative practitioner behavioral outcomes like corruption, collusion and bid rigging (Beth, 2007; OECD, 2009). From the data analysis it was found that integrity has significant effect on competitive tendering and bounded rationality. And also integrity has significant impact on association between competitive tendering and opportunism. These results were opposite of our prediction. It can be argued that existence of bounded rationality and opportunism in procurement transaction is a source of impractical behavioural to procurement practitioners. So, integrity itself may discourage practitioners to attain transparency, competition and value for money outstandingly. In a study by Ryan and Deci (2000) argued that highly integrity employees have tendency to be self-driven and they like to make their own rules to perform the tasks. Driving support from this finding is assumed that integrity may serve well independently at the same time buffer or magnify its effect on TCs and increase efficiency of competitive tendering in public procurement.


 CONCLUSION

The purpose of this paper was to examine moderating effect of integrity on transaction costs dimensions and competitive tendering. The objective was to bridge the gap between the literatures on effects behavioural aspects of transaction costs on competitive tendering. Generally, from the study results and findings, it can be concluded that to evaluate effects of integrity in competitive tendering, there is a need to determine the nature and sources of transaction costs in procurement procedures and, in particular, to see whether the occurrence transaction costs represent under-performance or inherently non-facilitative. However, efficiency gains of competitive tendering will generate net economic benefits to society from the better use of integrity in competitive tendering after taking into consideration existence of opportunism and bounded rationality.

By moderating transaction costs in competitive tendering by using integrity the study showed that it is possible and reasonable to consider a bounded rationality and opportunism simultaneously. In the theoretical discussion, the integrity of public procurement practitioners has gained a central position on enhancing efficiency of competitive tendering. The results fully support this. From the results it was seen that dimensions of integrity have a great effect on bounded rationality and opportunism as well. For example trusts, compliance, honesty, ethics and professional values better explain occurrence of moderation effect of integrity on transaction costs dimensions and competitive tendering.

 

In addition, the classification of behavioural effects is based on specific individual behaviour as somewhat mentioned in the previous literature. The literature acknowledges that trusts, compliance, honesty, ethics and professional values can change individual behaviour and thus reduces transaction costs in competitive tendering. However, there is a gap in attention on how accommodate different group strategies and perceptions when working together.

 

Moreover, most literature on public procurement rarely considers bounded rationality and opportunism as generic, mostly infectious surroundings of competitive tendering in public procurement. Little attention is paid to size and other characteristics of the integrity as a moderating factor on bounded rationality and opportunism. The results however suggest that bounded rationality and opportunism features affect competitive tendering. Thus future literature ought not to discuss transaction costs in a too general level but to take its characteristics into account. More attention should be paid to the bounded rationality and opportunism in competitive tendering, the behavioural relationships between participants and the openness of interfaces.


 IMPLICATIONS AND FUTURE DIRECTIONS

This study offers copious implications to knowledge of behavioural factors governing relational exchange in the context of integrity, transaction costs and competitive tendering in public procurement. Initially, this paper extends the familiarity on importance of behavioural relational aspects of competitive tendering in public procurement and contributes to fills the gap in existing literature through empirical evidence. Many scholars explore the effect of behavioural relational as an important tool which affects business performance minimising transaction cost. However, in the public procurement context, lack of indications reflects about the moderation effect of integrity on transaction costs in competitive tendering, particularly in developing countries. The study fills this gap by disclosing empirical evidence providing substantial contributions to empirical knowledge in the field of integrity, transaction costs and competitive tendering.

 

This study undergoes numerous limitations that should be addressed in future researches. Initially, the study only identifies few dimensions to reflect integrity, transaction costs and competitive tendering. Thus, several dimensions of integrity, transaction costs and competitive tendering have been addressed and identified by various scholars in the literature. Another limitation refers to the fact that the respondents in this survey came from Dodoma which largely relies on behavioural perspectives, which makes it inappropriate to generalize these conclusions to other world places of activity at once. On the other hand, the foremost limitation is the number of participants in our sample (n= 220), that it examines a very small subset of the total population (N= 978). Though Dodoma is involved in connection with respondents, but there are many other areas in Tanzania where public procurement is prevalent.

 

Therefore, further study is needed, possibly using a longitudinal case study and qualitative approach in a number of regions, to reveal patterns and the moderation effect of integrity on transaction costs in competitive tendering over time. There is a need to find a better blend and balance of what might be called moderating effect, and knowledge on the technical aspects of competitive tendering with other public procurement principles in different interactions. A well-developed systematic methodology is in need to be addressed in imminent researches to measure moderating aspects like transparency, accountability, and competition in a broader viewpoint of not only behavioural factors but also environmental factors.


 CONFLICT OF INTERESTS

The authors have not declared any conflicts of interests.


 ETHICAL CONSIDERATIONS

This article followed all ethical standards for research without direct contact with human or animal subjects.


 ACKNOWLEDGEMENT

The authors would like to thank practitioners and regulators in the field of public procurement for their sincere efforts and expertise. This work would not have been accomplished without their help.



 REFERENCES

Achua JK (2011). Anti-Corruption In Public Procurement In Nigeria: Challenges And Competency Strategies. Journal of Public Procurement 11(3):323-333.
Crossref

 

Ackah D, Agboyi MR, Adu-Gyamfi L, Enu P (2014). Competitive Tendering, an Effective Tool in Ensuring Value for Money in Public Sector Procurement: A Case Study at "Ahanta West District Assembly" A District in the Western Part of Ghana. Global Journal of Management Studies and Researches 1(4):186-201.

 

Adusei C, Awunyo-Vitor D (2015). Implementation challenges of the public procurement act by selected metropolitan, municipal and district assemblies in the Ashanti Region, Ghana. iBusiness 7(1):39.
Crossref

 

Agaba E, Shipman N (2007). Public procurement reform in developing countries: The Ugandan experience. Advancing Public Procurement: Practices, Innovation and Knowledge-Sharing 2(4):373-391.

 

Agerberg JN, Ågren J (2012). Risk management in the tendering process (A survey of risk management practices within infrastructural construction). Master of Science Thesis in the Masters Programme Design and Construction Project Management, Göteborg, Sweden.

 

Akaninyene OU, Mark J (2015). Effect of ethics and integrity on good public procurement system. AFRREV IJAH: An International Journal of Arts and Humanities 4(1):168-176.
Crossref

 

Alam Q, Pacher J (2000). Impact of compulsory competitive tendering on the structure and performance of local government systems in the State of Victoria. Public Administration and Development: The International Journal of Management Research and Practice 20(5):359-371.
Crossref

 

Alford J, Hughes O (2008). Public value pragmatism as the next phase of public management. The American Review of Public Administration 38(2):130-148.
Crossref

 

Amaral M, Saussier S, Yvrande-Billon A (2009). Auction procedures and competition in public services: The case of urban public transport in France and London. Utilities Policy 17(2):166-175.
Crossref

 

Amemba CS, Nyaboke PG, Osoro A, Mburu N (2013). Challenges affecting public procurement performance process in Kenya. International Journal of Research in Management 3(4):41-55.

 

Arbuckle JL (2007). AMOS (Version 7) [Computer software]. Chicago: SPSS.

 

Arjoon S (2005). Corporate governance: An ethical perspective. Journal of Business Ethics 61(4):343-352.
Crossref

 

Arrowsmith S, Linarelli J, Wallace D (2000). Regulation public procurement-national and international perspectives. Kluwer Law International BV.

 

Asare EN, Prempeh KB (2016). Measures of ensuring value for money in public procurement: A case of selected polytechnics in Ghana. Journal of Logistics Management 5(1):22-31.

 

Augier M (2016). Bounded Rationality: In: Augier M, Teece D (eds,). The Palgrave Encyclopedia of Strategic Management. Palgrave Macmillan, London.
Crossref

 

Awuor EO, Muthoni GB (2014). The Influence of Purchasing Maturity on Ethical Procurement in Kenya: A Survey of Procurement Professionals in Kenya.

 

Ayoti BN (2012). Factors influencing effectiveness in tendering process in public sector, the case of Nyeri County, Kenya. Doctoral dissertation, University of Nairobi, Kenya.

 

Balogun MJ (2003). Causative and enabling factors in public integrity: A focus on leadership, institutions, and character formation. Public Integrity 5(2):127-147.
Crossref

 

Baltos G, Doni L, Balodis J (2018). The international public procurement evolution: new strategic challenges met in collaboration with internal audit advisory services. Academic Journal of Interdisciplinary Studies 7:193-205.
Crossref

 

Banks S (2004). Professional integrity, social work and the ethics of distrust'. Social Work and Social Sciences Review 11(2):20-35.
Crossref

 

Barnard A, Schurink W, De Beer M (2008). A conceptual framework of integrity. SA Journal of Industrial Psychology 34(2):40-49.
Crossref

 

Bennet A, Bennet D (2008). The Decision-Making Process for Complex Situations in a Complex Environment, First chapter in Burstein, F. and Holsapple, CW. Handbook on Decision Support Systems.
Crossref

 

Bergh DD, Ketchen Jr DJ, Orlandi I, Heugens PP, Boyd BK (2019). Information asymmetry in management research: Past accomplishments and future opportunities. Journal of Management 45(1):122-158.
Crossref

 

Beth E (2007). Integrity in public procurement: Good practice from A to Z. Organisation for Economic Co-operation and Development (OECD).

 

Bovis CH (2006). Developing public procurement regulation: Jurisprudence and its influence on law making. Common Market and Law Review 43:461.
Crossref

 

Broms R, Dahlström C, Fazekas M (2019). Political competition and public procurement outcomes. Comparative Political Studies 52(9):1259-1292.
Crossref

 

Brook M (2016). Estimating and tendering for construction work. Taylor & Francis.
Crossref

 

Cabras I (2011). Mapping the spatial patterns of public procurement. International Journal of Public Sector Management 24(3):187-205.
Crossref

 

Caldwell N, Walker H, Harland C, Knight L, Zhen J, Wakeley T (2005). Promoting competitive markets: The role of public procurement. Journal of Purchasing and Supply Management 11(5-6):242-251.
Crossref

 

Carr JB, LeRoux K, Feiock R, Shrestha M (2007). Trust, transaction costs, and service production decisions: An institutional collective action explanation. 9th National Public Management Research Conference, Tucson, Arizona.

 

Chesbrough HW (2006). Open Business Models: How to Thrive in the New Innovation Landscape. Boston, MA: Harvard Business School Press.

 

Childers WH (2009). Transformational leadership and its relationship to trust and behavioral integrity. Saybrook University.

 

Cordelia A (2006). Transaction costs and information systems: does IT add up? Journal of Information Technology 21(3):195-202.
Crossref

 

Cox JF, Pearce CL, Perry M (2003). Toward a model of shared leadership and distributed influence in the innovation process: How shared leadership can enhance new product development team dynamics and effectiveness. In: Pearce CL, Conger JA (eds.), Shared leadership: Reframing the How's and Whys of leadership. pp. 48-68.
Crossref

 

Darabad BG (2017). The Principle of Competition-The Key To Public Procurement Regulation. European Journal of Social Sciences Studies 2(6):93-100.

 

Das TK, Teng BS (2004). The risk-based view of trust: A conceptual framework. Journal of Business and Psychology 19(1):85-116.
Crossref

 

Dean T (2015). Building Better Public Services: A Guide for Practitioners. Friesen Press.

 

Dimitri N, Piga G, Spagnolo G (2006). Handbook of procurement. Cambridge University Press.
Crossref

 

Dorward A (2001). The effects of transaction costs, power and risk on contractual arrangements: a conceptual framework for quantitative analysis. Journal of Agricultural Economics 52(2):59-73.
Crossref

 

Dowall D, Whittington J (2008). Transaction-Cost Economic Analysis of Institutional Change toward Design-Build Contracts for Public Transportation.

 

Dunn CP (2009). Integrity matters. International Journal of Leadership Studies 5(2):102-125.

 

Eisenbeib SA, Brodbeck F (2014). Ethical and unethical leadership: A cross-cultural and cross-sectoral analysis. Journal of Business Ethics 122(2):343-359.
Crossref

 

Erhard W, Jensen MC, Zaffron S (2009). A new model of integrity: An actionable pathway to trust, productivity and value (PDF File of Keynote Slides).
Crossref

 

Erridge A, Fee R, McIlroy J (1999). An assessment of competitive tendering using transaction cost analysis. Public Money and Management 19(3):37-42.
Crossref

 

Erridge A, McIlroy J (2002). Public procurement and supply management strategies. Public Policy and Administration 17(1):52-71.
Crossref

 

Evenett SJ (2002). The WTO government procurement agreement: an assessment of current research and options for reform. In World Bank conference. Informing the Doha Process: New Trade Research for Developing Economies," Cairo, Egypt.

 

Eyaa S, Oluka PN (2011). Explaining non-compliance in public procurement in Uganda. International Journal of Business and Social Science 2:11.

 

Foss NJ (2003). Bounded rationality in the economics of organization. "Much cited and little used. Journal of Economic Psychology 24(2):245-264.
Crossref

 

Frankel T (2005). Trust and honesty: America's business culture at a crossroad. Oxford University Press.

 

Furrer O, Tjemkes B, Aydinlik AÜ, Yaslioglu M, Bas T (2013). The effect of individualism on opportunism propensity in international strategic alliances. working paper, Radboud University, Nijmegen.
Crossref

 

Gaziano TF (2000). The use and abuse of executive orders and other presidential directives. Available at:

View

 

Gebler D (2006). Creating an ethical culture. Strategic Finance 87(11):28.

 

Gelderman CJ, Paul WT, Brugman MJ (2006). Public procurement and EU tendering directives-explaining non?compliance. International Journal of Public Sector Management 19(7):702-714.
Crossref

 

Georghiou L, Edler J, Uyarra E, Yeow J (2014). Policy instruments for public procurement of innovation: Choice, design and assessment. Technological Forecasting and Social Change 86:1-12.
Crossref

 

Ghozali I (2005). Application of multivariate analysis with SPSS. Semarang: UNDIP Publishing Agency.

 

Gigerenzer G, Selten R (2002). Bounded rationality: The adaptive toolbox. MIT Press.
Crossref

 

Graells AS (2016). Public procurement and competition: some challenges arising from recent developments in EU public procurement law. Research Handbook on EU Public Procurement Law. Edward Elgar Publishing.
Crossref

 

Guide on Public Procurement and Competition (2011) Available at:

View

 

Haack S (2007). The integrity of science: What it means, why it matters. Contrastes: Revista International de Filosofia 12:5-26.
Crossref

 

Handfield R (2014). Role of procurement within an organization: Procurement: A tutorial.

 

Hansson L, Holmgren J (2011). Bypassing public procurement regulation: A study of rationality in local decision making. Regulation and Governance 5(3):368-385.
Crossref

 

Hawkins TG (2007). Explaining Buyer Opportunism in Business-to-Business Relationships.

 

Heggstad K, Frøystad M, Isaksen J (2010). The basics of integrity in procurement: A guidebook. Chr. Michelsen Institute, Bergen, Norway.

 

Hennart JF (2010). Transaction cost theory and international business. Journal of Retailing 86(3):257-269.
Crossref

 

Hensher DA, Wallis IP (2005). Competitive tendering as a contracting mechanism for subsidising transport: the bus experience. Journal of Transport Economics and Policy 39(3):295-322.

 

Hernández JGV, Ortega RP (2019). Bounded rationality in decision-making. MOJ Research Review 2(1):1-8.
Crossref

 

Hill CWL (1990). Cooperation, opportunism, and the invisible hand: implications for transaction cost theory. Academy of Management Review 15(3):500-513.
Crossref

 

Ho SP, Tsui CW (2009). The transaction costs of Public-Private Partnerships: implications on PPP governance design. In Lead 2009 Specialty Conference: Global Governance in Project Organizations, South Lake Tahoe, CA, pp. 5-7.

 

Hoang LA, Castella JC, Novosad P (2006). Social networks and information access: Implications for agricultural extension in a rice farming community in northern Vietnam. Agriculture and Human Values 23(4):513-527.
Crossref

 

Hobbs JE (1996). A transaction cost approach to supply chain management. Supply Chain Management 1(2):15-27.
Crossref

 

Hodgson GM (2004). Opportunism is not the only reason why firms exist: why an explanatory emphasis on opportunism may mislead management strategy. Industrial and Corporate Change 13(2):401-418.
Crossref

 

Holtz B (2005). Human Knowledge: Foundations and Limits. ©Brian Holtz.

View

 

Hu LT, Bentler PM (1995). Evaluating model fit. In R. H. Hoyle (Ed.), Structural equation modeling: Concepts, issues, and applications. Sage Publications, Incorporated. pp. 76-99.

 

Hunja RR (2003). Obstacles to public procurement reform in developing countries. Public Procurement: The Continuing Revolution, Kluwer Law International pp. 13-22.

 

Huo B, Ye Y, Zhao X (2015). The impacts of trust and contracts on opportunism in the 3PL industry: The moderating role of demand uncertainty. International Journal of Production Economics 170:160-170.
Crossref

 

Ishak NB, Eze UC, Ling LS (2010). Integrating knowledge management and human resource management for sustainable performance. Journal of Organizational Knowledge Management 2010:1-13.
Crossref

 

Jensen MC (2009). Integrity: Without it Nothing Works Rotman Magazine: The Magazine of the Rotman School of Management. Harvard Business School NOM Unit Working Paper No. 10-042; Barbados Group Working Paper No. 09-04.

 

Jeppesen R (2010). Accountability in public procurement: Transparency and the role of civil society. United Nations Procurement Capacity Development Centre.

 

Jibrin MS, Ejura SB, Augustine NI (2014). The public procurement reforms in Nigeria: Implementation and compliance challenges. Journal of Asian Business Strategy 4(11):149.

 

John G (1984). An empirical investigation of some antecedents of opportunism in a marketing channel. Journal of Marketing Research 21(3):278-289.
Crossref

 

Jonah UI (2018). The influence of transaction costs on the Business Performances of Tesco Supermarket. Available at:

View

 

Jones BD (2017). Behavioral rationality as a foundation for public policy studies. Cognitive Systems Research 43:63-75.
Crossref

 

Jun M, Cai S, Shin H (2006). TQM practice in maquiladora: Antecedents of employee satisfaction and loyalty. Journal of Operations Management 24(6):791-812.
Crossref

 

Jur?ík R (2014). Public procurement in the field of public administration in the Czech Republic, selected aspects. WSEAS Transactions on Business and Economics 11(57):615-624.

 

Kang BG, Elbashier MMME, Tang L, Jin R, Tang S (2018). Competitive tendering for construction projects in Sudan. Journal of Fundamental and Applied Sciences 10(3S):828-835.

 

Karthikeyan C (2017). A Meta Analytical Study on Leadership Integrity: A leadership Ethics Perspective. International Journal of Management, IT and Engineering 7(4):240-263.

 

Kaspar L, Puddephatt A (2012). Benefits of transparency in public procurement for SMEs. Available at:

View

 

Kauppi K, Van Raaij EM (2015). Opportunism and honest incompetence-seeking explanations for noncompliance in public procurement. Journal of Public Administration Research and Theory 25(3):953-979.
Crossref

 

Khan N (2018). Public Procurement Fundamentals: Lessons from and for the Field. Emerald Group Publishing.
Crossref

 

Kiage JO (2013). Factors affecting procurement performance: A case of ministry of energy. International Journal of Business and Commerce 3(1):54-70.

 

Kline T (2005). Psychological testing: A practical approach to design and evaluation. Sage.
Crossref

 

Kruse KM (2019). From me to we.

View

 

Kutosi AM, Moses M, Eya S (2015). Contracting and Behavioural Practices in State Owned Enterprises in Uganda. International Journal of Social Science and Economics Invention 1(01):1-12.
Crossref

 

Lager JM (2009). Overcoming cultures of compliance to reduce corruption and achieve ethics in government. McGeorge Law Review pp. 41-63.

 

Lennick D, Kiel F (2007). Moral intelligence: Enhancing business performance and leadership success. Pearson Prentice Hall.

 

Lingard H, Hughes W, Chinyio E (1998). The impact of contractor selection method on transaction costs: a review. Journal of Construction Procurement 4(2):89-102.

 

Lodhia SK, Burritt RL (2004). Public sector accountability failure in an emerging economy. International Journal of Public Sector Management 17(4):345-359.
Crossref

 

Lunenburg FC (2010). The decision making process. In National Forum of Educational Administration and Supervision Journal 27(4):1-12.

 

Lynch J, Angel J (2013). Public Procurement: Principles, Categories and Methods. Available at:

View

 

Lysons K, Farrington B (2010). Purchasing and supply chain management. Pearson Education India.

 

Mantzaris EA (2014). Public procurement, tendering and corruption: Realities, challenges and tangible solutions. Available at:

View

 

Manu C (2005). The principle of value for money in procurement.

 

Mathisen TA, Solvoll G (2008). Competitive tendering and structural changes: An example from the bus industry. Transport Policy 15(1):1-11.
Crossref

 

Mayavi HP (2013). An assessment of tendering procedures in public Organization The case of college of business education (CBE) (Doctoral dissertation, Mzumbe University).

 

McCrudden C, Gross SG (2006). WTO government procurement rules and the local dynamics of procurement policies: a Malaysian case study. European Journal of International Law 17(1):151-185.
Crossref

 

Menzel DC (2015). Research on ethics and integrity in public administration: Moving forward, looking back. Public Integrity 17(4):343-370.
Crossref

 

Merry S, Power N, McManus M, Alison L (2012). Drivers of public trust and confidence in police in the UK. International Journal of Police Science and Management 14(2):118-135.
Crossref

 

Montgomery DC, Runger GC, Hubele NF (2009). Engineering statistics. John Wiley & Sons.

 

Moorman RH, Grover S (2009). Why does leader integrity matter to followers? An uncertainty management-based explanation. International Journal of Leadership Studies 5(2):102-114.

 

Moronda GB (2014). Factors affecting tendering process in public Sector: The case of ministry of health and social Welfare (Doctoral dissertation, Mzumbe University).

 

Mroczek-D?browska K, Gorynia M (2019). Understanding Transaction Costs in the Mesoeconomic Perspective. Argumenta Oeconomica 1(42):337-360.
Crossref

 

Musanzikwa M (2013). Public procurement system challenges in developing countries: The case of Zimbabwe. International Journal of Economics, Finance and Management Sciences 1(2):119-127.
Crossref

 

Mwandobo LJ (2013). The Role of Procurement Processes on the effectiveness of Public Procurement System in Tanzania. Doctoral dissertation, The Open University of Tanzania.

 

Naidoo G (2012). The critical need for ethical leadership to curb corruption and promote good governance in the South African public sector. Journal of Public Administration 47(3):656-683.

 

Ngugi JK, Mugo HW (2012). Internal factors affecting procurement process of supplies in the public sector; a survey of Kenya government ministries. 5th International Public Procurement Conference was held on August 17th.

 

Nikolaeva E, Pletnev D (2016). The Role of the Transaction Costs in the Business Success of Small and Medium Sized Enterprises in Russia. Procedia Social and Behavioral Sciences 221:176-184.
Crossref

 

Ntayi JM, Ngoboka P, Kakooza CS (2013). Moral schemas and corruption in Ugandan public procurement. Journal of Business Ethics 112(3):417-436.
Crossref

 

Office of Government Commerce (2007). The official introduction to the ITIL service lifecycle. The Stationery Office.

 

Oluka PN (2013). Public Procurement Reforms: Issues and Challenges: The case of Uganda. In Presentation at the CIPS Pan African Conference 21-22 at National Theatre, Ghana.

 

Önder Ç, Erdil SE (2017). Opportunities and opportunism: Publication outlet selection under pressure to increase research productivity. Research Evaluation 26(2):66-77.
Crossref

 

Organisation for Economic Co-operation and Development (OECD) (2009). OECD principles for integrity in public procurement. OECD Publishing.

 

Osei-Afoakwa K (2012) What makes corruption in the public procurement process awful? International Journal of Development and Sustainability 1:3.

 

Ozkan-Tektas O (2014). The effects of opportunism and trust on buyer-supplier relationship: Do commitment types matter. International Journal of Business and Social Research 4(9):14-26.

 

Palanski ME, Kahai SS, Yammarino FJ (2011). Team virtues and performance: An examination of transparency, behavioral integrity, and trust. Journal of Business Ethics 99(2):201-216.
Crossref

 

Palanski ME, Yammarino FJ (2011). Impact of behavioral integrity on follower job performance: A three-study examination. The Leadership Quarterly 22(4):765-786.
Crossref

 

Parker D, Hartley K (2003). Transaction costs, relational contracting and public private partnerships: a case study of UK defence. Journal of Purchasing and Supply Management 9(3):97-108.
Crossref

 

Petrovic D, Milos K (2011). Transaction costs and the efficiency of institutions. Facta Universitatis 8(4):379-387.

 

Ping Ho S, Levitt R, Tsui CW, Hsu Y (2015). Opportunism-focused transaction cost analysis of public-private partnerships. Journal of Management in Engineering 31(6):04015007.
Crossref

 

Poorchangizi B, Borhani F, Abbaszadeh A, Mirzaee M, Farokhzadian J (2019). The importance of professional values from nursing students' perspective. BMC Nursing 18(1):26.
Crossref

 

Priyanath S, Buthsala A (2017). Information, opportunism and business performance: A case of small businesses managed by women entrepreneurs in Sri Lanka. Asian Journal of Multidisciplinary Studies 5(11):230-239.

 

Priyanto E, Maryunani G, Khusaini M (2014). Effects of asymmetric information, transaction cost to corporate governance, and public organization performance. IOSR Journal of Business and Management 15(6):14-27.
Crossref

 

Prottas DJ (2008). Perceived behavioral integrity: Relationships with employee attitudes, well-being, and absenteeism. Journal of Business Ethics 81(2):313-322.
Crossref

 

Puranam P, Stieglitz N, Osman M, Pillutla MM (2015). Modelling bounded rationality in organizations: Progress and prospects. Academy of Management Annals 9(1):337-392.
Crossref

 

Qaqaya H, Lipimile G (2008). The effects of anti-competitive business practices on developing countries and their development prospects. United Nations Conference on Trade and Development. United Nations. No. UNCT AD/DITC/CLP/2008/2. New York: United States of America.

 

Rajeh M, Tookey JE, Rotimi JOB (2013). Determining the magnitude of transaction costs in construction procurement systems: An exploratory study. World Building Congress. Available at: View

 

Raymond J (2008). Benchmarking in public procurement. Benchmarking: An International Journal 15(6):782-793.
Crossref

 

Reeves E (2008). The practice of contracting in public private partnerships: Transaction costs and relational contracting in the Irish schools sector. Public Administration 86(4):969-986.
Crossref

 

Rivasplata C (2002). The role of competitive tendering in transport integration: the cases of Chile and South Africa. In urban mobility for all. Proceedings of the 10th International Codatu Conference. Available at:

View

 

Rohr JA (2008). Ethics and integrity of governance: Perspectives across frontiers. Edward Elgar Publishing.

 

Roman AV (2017). Tracing the effects of politicization on public procurement specialists' decision-making through values: A structural equation model of the broker-purist lens. Journal of Public Procurement 17(1):53-88.
Crossref

 

Ryan RM, Deci EL (2000). Intrinsic and extrinsic motivations: Classic definitions and new directions. Contemporary Educational Psychology 25(1):54-67.
Crossref

 

Sanchez-Graells A (2011). A Critical Appraisal of the Spanish National Competition Commission's Guide on Public Procurement and Competition (Una Visión Crítica de la'Guía Sobre Contratación Pública y Competencia'Publicada por la CNC) (in Spanish). Gaceta Jurídica de la Unión Europea y de la Competencia. Available at:

View

 

Schapper PR, Malta JNV, Gilbert DL (2006). An analytical framework for the management and reform of public procurement. Journal of Public Procurement 6(1/2):1-26.
Crossref

 

Schieg M (2008). Strategies for avoiding asymmetric information in construction project management. Journal of Business Economics and Management 1:47-51.
Crossref

 

Seeletse S, Ladzani W (2012). Project cost estimation techniques used by most emerging building contractors of South Africa. Acta Structilia 19(1):106-125.

 

Shannon BN, McGee ZA, Jones BD (2019). Bounded Rationality and Cognitive Limits in Political Decision Making. Oxford Research Encyclopedia of Politics. Available at:
Crossref

 

Singh A, Dhumale R (2001). Competition policy, development, and developing countries. In What Global Economic Crisis? Palgrave Macmillan, London pp. 122-145.
Crossref

 

Sit WY, Ooi KB, Lin B, Chong AYL (2009). TQM and customer satisfaction in Malaysia's service sector. Industrial Management and Data Systems 109(7):957-975.
Crossref

 

Smith AJ (2017). Estimating, Tendering and Bidding for Construction Work. Macmillan International Higher Education.

 

Somera K, Holt MK (2015). Integrity in business: An evaluation of integrity across German and American culture. International Journal of Business and Social Science 6(2):32-36.

 

Søreide T (2002). Corruption in public procurement. Causes, consequences and cures. Chr. Michelsen Institute.

 

Steane PD, Walker DHT (2000). Competitive tendering and contracting public sector services in Australia-a facilities management issue. Facilities 18(5/6):245-255.
Crossref

 

Tabish SZS, Jha KN (2011). Analyses and evaluation of irregularities in public procurement in India. Construction Management and Economics 29(3):261-274.
Crossref

 

Tadelis S, Bajari P (2006). Incentives and award procedures: competitive tendering vs. negotiations in procurement. Handbook of Procurement 121:39.
Crossref

 

Tan LHJ (2013). An analysis of internal controls and procurement fraud deterrence. Doctoral dissertation, Monterey, California: Naval Postgraduate School.

 

Testa F, Annunziata E, Iraldo F, Frey M (2016). Drawbacks and opportunities of green public procurement: an effective tool for sustainable production. Journal of Cleaner Production 112:1893-1900.
Crossref

 

Thai KV (2001). Public procurement re-examined. Journal of Public Procurement 1(1):9-50.
Crossref

 

Thai KV (2017). International public procurement: Concepts and practices. In International handbook of public procurement. Routledge pp. 1-24.
Crossref

 

The Victorian Government (2019). Achieving value for money - goods and services procurement guide. Available at:

View

 

Thomassen K, Vassbø S, Solheim-Kile E, Lohne J (2016). Public-private partnership: Transaction costs of tendering. Procedia Computer Science 100:818-825.
Crossref

 

Todorova T (2016). Transaction Costs, Market Failures and Economic Development. Journal of Advanced Research in Law and Economics 7(17):678-684.

 

Tomlinson EC, Lewicki RJ, Ash SR (2014). Disentangling the moral integrity construct: Values congruence as a moderator of the behavioral integrity-citizenship relationship. Group and Organization Management 39(6):720-743.
Crossref

 

Tremblay M, Martineau JT, Pauchant TC (2017). Managing organizational ethics in the public sector: A pluralist contingency approach as an alternative to the integrity management framework. Public Integrity 19(3):219-233.
Crossref

 

Tukuta M, Saruchera F (2015). Challenges facing procurement professionals in developing economies: Unlocking value through professional international purchasing. Journal of Transport and Supply Chain Management 9(1):1-9.
Crossref

 

Tyler TR (2001). Public trust and confidence in legal authorities: What do majority and minority group members want from the law and legal institutions? Behavioral Sciences and the Law 19(2):215-235.
Crossref

 

Udechukwu II (2007). Integrity: The Courage to Meet the Demands of Reality. Journal of Applied Management and Entrepreneurship 12(2):106.

 

Ugwu MO (2018). Perceptions of Unrestricted Gift Giving and the Integrity of Public Servants in Nigeria.
Crossref

 

Uzonwanne FC (2016). Rational Model of Decision Making. Global Encyclopedia of Public Administration, Public Policy, and Governance pp. 1-6.
Crossref

 

Valéro V (2015). Government opportunism in public?private partnerships. Journal of Public Economic Theory 17(1):111-135.
Crossref

 

Vallario CW (2007). Is your ethics program working? A business with strong ethical behavior enhances and preserves its reputation, inspires loyalty and advertises that it has its ethics message right. It also fosters an ethical culture within the organization. Financial Executive 23(4):26-29.

 

Wang H, Rosenau JN (2001). Transparency international and corruption as an issue of global governance. Global Governance: A Review of Multilateralism and International Organizations 7(1):25-49.
Crossref

 

Williams S, Quinot G (2007). Public procurement and corruption: the South African response. South African Law Journal 124(2):339-363.

 

Williams-Elegbe S (2015). A comparative analysis of the Nigerian Public Procurement Act against international best practice. Journal of African Law 59(01):85-98.
Crossref

 

Williamson OE (1975). Markets and Hierarchies: Analysis and Antitrust Implications. New York: The Free Press.

 

Williamson OE (1985). The economic institutions of capitalism. New York: Free Press.

 

Williamson OE (2008). Outsourcing: Transaction cost economics and supply chain management. Journal of Supply Chain Management 44(2):5-16.
Crossref

 

Wittig WA, Jeng H (2005). Challenges in public procurement: Comparative views of public procurement reform in Gambia. KV Thai, International Handbook of Public Procurement, pp. 21-36.

 

World Bank (2003). Ghana 2003 Country Procurement Assessment Report, Washington, DC: Ghana Country.

 

Yahaya ML, Oyediran OS, Onukuwbe HN (2019). Evaluating Factors Affecting Transaction Costs of Contractors in Public Procurement in Nigeria: PLS-SEM Approach. FUTY Journal of the Environment 13(1):46-64.

 

Yakovlev A, Tkachenko A, Demidova O, Balaeva O (2015). The impacts of different regulatory regimes on the effectiveness of public procurement. International Journal of Public Administration 38(11):796-814.
Crossref

 

Yang L, Toubia O, De Jong MG (2015). A bounded rationality model of information search and choice in preference measurement. Journal of Marketing Research 52(2):166-183.
Crossref

 




          */?>