African Journal of
Marketing Management

  • Abbreviation: Afr. J. Mark. Manage.
  • Language: English
  • ISSN: 2141-2421
  • DOI: 10.5897/AJMM
  • Start Year: 2009
  • Published Articles: 159

Full Length Research Paper

Marketing of Jew’s mallow in Agbedranfo local area in the Southwest of Benin

Patrice Ygué Adegbola
  • Patrice Ygué Adegbola
  • Agricultural Research Center of Agonkanmey (CRA-Agonkanmey), National Institute of Agricultural Researches of Benin (INRAB), Benin.
  • Google Scholar
Christelle Marie Komlan-Ahihou
  • Christelle Marie Komlan-Ahihou
  • Agricultural Research Center of Agonkanmey (CRA-Agonkanmey), National Institute of Agricultural Researches of Benin (INRAB), Benin.
  • Google Scholar
Anselme Adegbidi
  • Anselme Adegbidi
  • Agricultural Research Center of Agonkanmey (CRA-Agonkanmey), National Institute of Agricultural Researches of Benin (INRAB), Benin.
  • Google Scholar
Sounkoura Adetonah
  • Sounkoura Adetonah
  • Agricultural Research Center of Agonkanmey (CRA-Agonkanmey), National Institute of Agricultural Researches of Benin (INRAB), Benin.
  • Google Scholar
Ousmane Coulibaly
  • Ousmane Coulibaly
  • Agricultural Research Center of Agonkanmey (CRA-Agonkanmey), National Institute of Agricultural Researches of Benin (INRAB), Benin.
  • Google Scholar
Guy-Apollinaire Mensah
  • Guy-Apollinaire Mensah
  • Agricultural Research Center of Agonkanmey (CRA-Agonkanmey), National Institute of Agricultural Researches of Benin (INRAB), Benin.
  • Google Scholar
Cocou Muriel Dorian Montcho
  • Cocou Muriel Dorian Montcho
  • Agricultural Research Center of Agonkanmey (CRA-Agonkanmey), National Institute of Agricultural Researches of Benin (INRAB), Benin.
  • Google Scholar


  •  Received: 10 February 2016
  •  Accepted: 18 May 2016
  •  Published: 30 June 2016

 ABSTRACT

This study focuses on analyzing the functioning of the marketing systems of jew’s mallow (Corchorus olitorius) produced in Agbédranfo (Dogbo), Southwest Benin. The methodological approach used was based on the Structure-Conduct-Performance paradigm (SCPA). A total of 60 producers, 28 retailers and 4 wholesalers were sampled. The results identified two jew’s mallow marketing systems based on sales periods and production locations: marketing system of jew’s mallow production was based on lowlands and of upland jew’s mallow marketing system. The net margin for jew’s mallow produced in Agbédranfo was 3.24 for producers, 9.67 for retailers and 8.37 for wholesalers in lowland jew’s mallow marketing system. However, the relative net margins of these actors in the marketing system of upland jew’s mallow were low. Moreover, a Gini coefficient of 0.34 showed an equal distribution of the gross margins obtained in the marketing system of lowland jew’s mallow. The study therefore, concludes that wholesalers and retailers have higher net margins than producers. Thus, a dialogue between marketing stakeholders themselves, extension agents, non-governmental oragnisations (NGOs), and public authorities is therefore desired.

 

Key words: Jew’s mallow, marketing, profitability, SCP paradigm, margin.


 INTRODUCTION

In Benin, market gardener is becoming more and more important socio-economically because of the number of actors who directly or indirectly make a living from it. Lowlands, considered as of no interest in the past, are now recognized as potentially adapted to truck farming. Jew’s mallow (Corchorus olitorius L.), commonly called “crincrin” is one of the market gardener products most cultivated (Savi, 2009). Among favorable regions for garden production in Benin are the municipalities of Houeyogbé and Dogbo in the Mono-Couffo departments in the Southwest. These municipalities are known for their agricultural potential, as they have had local markets for the marketing of garden crops for decades (Savi, 2009).

In Benin, the departments of the Mono/ Couffo contributed 11.89% of the production in 2002, and 14.43% in 2003 (DPP/MAEP, 2008) whereas in 2007 this production passed over 23.692 tons in this area compared to a total of 293.705 tons for the whole country making it about 8.1% of total production (INSAE, 2008). This part of the national production puts the department of the Mono/Couffo in third position in relation to the other. The Ouémé/Plateau takes the head of the ordering followed by the Atlantic / Littoral which total production in 2007 was 164.263 tons (INSAE, 2008). Among the big zones of production in Benin, besides the urban and out-of-town zones, some specific zones such as the valleys are major zones that provide various products to the urban consumers. In the valley regions, the production of local and exotic vegetables (lettuce, string bean, carrot, cabbage, cucumber, beet etc.) are all year round due to irrigation (Adegbola and Singbo, 2001). These cultures are practiced only once a year during the period of subsidence (period of low waters) (Singbo and Nouhoeflin, 2005). 

In contrast to the earlier affirmations, in the valley of the Mono, the jew’s mallow is cultivated three times in the year. It is a leafy vegetable that is appreciated in the diet of the majority of the Beninese populations living in the South. The production of this commodity constitutes an activity that occupies majority of the producers notably women who pull from it the necessary income to the satisfaction of their essential needs. It is justified by the weak production of the only product of pension formerly recognized (the oil palm tree) which doesn't satisfy anymore the majority because of its weak productivity and its specificity. This production becomes more and more very uncertain after the climatic disruptions and its fashion of traditional production.

This specialization of the valley of the Mono in the production and marketing of jew’s mallow, doesn't still make it the object of serious socioeconomic investigation. Savi (2009) analyzed the financial profitability and the technical, and economic efficiency of the production of the jew’s mallow (Corchorus olitorius) in the Mono valley in Benin. Jew’s mallow ranks fifth among the most consumed vegetable in the largest town of Benin (Cotonou) after tomato, onion, pepper and cowpea (Guidi, 2007). Each citizen of this town consumes about 12.78 g per capita per day. In fact, jew’s mallow is an important source of nutrient because of its high vitamin, beta carotene and soluble and insoluble fiber content which have a beneficial effect on the intestine mucosa (Soro et al., 2012). Moreover, it is highly marketed because of the sticky aspect of its sauce which is really appreciated by consumers (FAFA, 2009). It is produced in the uplands as well as in the lowlands, and it is considered as a product highly meant for sale (Savi, 2009).

A study conducted by Santara (2009) on the profitability of the cropping systems in the lowlands of Agbédranfo, Vovokanmey and Houinga-Houégbé in the Mono-Couffo departments, has shown that in the lowland of Agbédranfo, jew’s mallow based crop system is the most profitable for small producers. Despite its importance in both economic and  nutritional  security,  jew’s  mallow  is one of the neglected and underutilized crops by research and development institutions. Two fundamental reasons may explain this situation: its nature as a minor crops and its specificity as a leafy vegetable, which is generally highly perishable, then expensive to store (Savi, 2009).

In this context, value addition to jew’s mallow produced in Agbédranfo should go through an effective marketing system. Jew’s mallow is marketed a lot because it is prepared in most households of the South-Benin with sauces (FAFA, 2009). Besides, the Jew's Mallow is the subject of important commercial exchanges with the neighboring countries. However, in Benin, the marketing of agricultural products is subject to many constrains such as market distortions and imperfections (Lutz, 1994; Kuiper et al., 1999, 2003; Lutz et al., 2006). For example, marketing system is sometimes confronted with efficiency problems in carrying out technical marketing operations, efficiency and equity in price formation and problems of ex post and mainly ex ante adjustment between production and consumption (Bergmann, 1960; Lutz et al., 2006).

Unfortunately, few reliable statistical data on its production and its sales are available; there is no statistical data on these exchanges (Agossou et al., 2001; Assogba, 2010). It is in order to bridge this knowledge gap on the merchandising of the vegetables that this research on the marketing of the Jew's Mallow produced in the shallows of the South-Benin in the department of the Mono Couffo, more particularly the Jew's Mallow produced at Agbédranfo was conducted.

This study thus focuses on the marketing of jew’s mallow at Agbédranfo in Mono. From this view, this work looks at the different actors along the value chain as the producers and traders, and their partners who are the research centers and the policy decision-makers.

  Theoretical framework: Structure-conduct- performance approach

The economic performance analysis of the markets uses theoretical bases taken from neoclassic theory. The limits of that theory are filled up by new economic approaches grounded on the interdisciplinarity necessary to any market study as socioeconomic institutions. At the operational level, market efficiency is assessed by analyzing the Structure-Conduct-Performance (SCP) which has had many applications in Africa, and is being improved through new tools of institutional and functional analysis of agricultural sectors (Demont et al., 2003; Mastaki, 2006).

Derived from the neoclassic theory, the Structure-Conduct-Performance paradigm was developed by the Harvard school and made popular during the years 1940 to 1960 with a study highlighting the correlations that may exist between the structure and the performance of the industry (Bain, 1951; Olagunju et al., 2012). The SCP paradigm concepts were developed from 1960 to 1990. These are the price theory, the econometric estimation (Demsetz et al., 1973; Peltzman, 1976; Becker), the game theory with an interest on strategic decision-making and Nash equilibrium concept (Tirole, 1988). After 1990, the reverse relationship between the degree of concentration of the market and the degree of competition has been the hypothesis behind the SCP hypothesis of the market. This is why market concentration encourages enterprises to partner. More precisely, the standard paradigm of the SCP asserts that there is a direct relationship between the degree of the market concentration and the degree of competition between enterprises.

This hypothesis will be retained if there is a relationship between the market concentration and the performance, no matter the efficiency of the enterprise. Thus, enterprises of the more concentrated sectors will gain higher profits than enterprises operating in less concentrated sectors, irrespective of their efficiency (Olagunju et al., 2012). The SCP approach implies therefore that the structure of a market, and particularly the degree of competition met there, determines the market behavior, and that the structure and the behavior taken together determine their performances (Demont et al., 2003; Tollens, 1997). These three indivisible elements – market structure, conduct of the actors and market performance – were defined according to Clodius and Muêller (1961) as follows:

Market structure is defined as the entire organizational characteristics that determine the relationships between protagonists (buyers and sellers); whether they are active or potential actors. Specifically in the frame of this study, research activities have been oriented here towards the degree of market concentration, that is the number of actors (wholesalers, retailers, etc.) and their distribution by size, the degree of product differentiation and the market entry and exit conditions. The market structure helps in describing market infrastructures. Bain (1968), Pomeroy and Trinidad (1998) and Ninglepong (2004) assert that market structure is characterized by its organization. This organization may influence strategically the nature of competition and the mode of price fixing inside the market.

Actors’ conduct refers to the models of behaviors actors follow and the strategies they use to adapt or adjust themselves to the markets in which they sell or buy. These strategies depend on the market structure, the individual power of traders in the market and on available assets. In this study, the market conduct is tackled based on the practices of the offer, that is, the strategies and arguments used by actors in price negotiation, the mode of payment used and finally on the degree of communication among actors.

Market performance expresses the economic results of all enterprises of the market. It translates the economic result of the structure and the conduct. It takes into account the existing relationships between the margins and the production cost of marketing services (effectiveness of the market performance) (Hariss, 1993).

In the frame of this study, this paradigm is the order to better structure the aspects of the problem. Table 1 shows the different elements of the SCP on which this study is based.


 M

Study area, sampling and data collection method

This study was carried out in the Couffo department, and covered jew’s mallow produced in Agbédranfo village (municipality of Dogbo) (Figure 1). Among the three (3) intervention sites of the project "Realizing the potential of agricultural inland valley lowlands in sub-Saharan Africa while maintaining their environmental services", coordinated by AfricaRice, the village of Agbédranfo was chosen because of the high production of jew’s mallow due to the high level of land development (Santara, 2009).

The sampling was done by category of actors, and was purposive. A total of 60 producers out of 280 producers in the village, 28 retailers and 4 wholesalers were sampled. The marketers (retailers and wholesalers) were surveyed in neighboring markets (Dogbo, Azovè and Lokossa) on the market day, because most of the women retailers, customers and producers-collectors from Agbédranfo frequented these markets. Group and individual discussions were made using a structured questionnaire depending on each category of actors.

Methods of analyses

Different statistical tools were used. Descriptive statistics (average, mode, minimum, maximum, crossed tables, standard deviation, frequency) were used to carry out market structure, particularly socioeconomic characteristics of producers and traders. They were used to illustrate some behaviors of the market actors.

Mapping the marketing channels

Mapping is the most essential activity, and the core of any marketing system analysis. The objective is to give an illustration of the identified actors, the marketing chain and the flow of related products. The different phases to achieve this mapping are:

1. Identification of the links of the marketing system

2. Identification of the major actors at the micro level.

3. Distinction of the channels if necessary, and identification of the nature of business linkages.

Calculation of the margins

The performance of the marketing systems studied was evaluated through the calculation of the margins and the equity.

1. At the level of producers: The calculations of the production gross and net margin are represented respectively by the equation (1) and (2) that is, Let us point out that producers sell their own product on the market, and that some of them also buy Jew’s mallow from other producers. However, in calculations, we were interested only in men and women producers who sell themselves their produce in the market.

2. At the level of women retailers and wholesalers: The calculation of the gross and net margin at the level of retailers and wholesalers is presented respectively in the equation (3) and (4) that is,

These margins calculated at the level of the different actors were then reported based on the unit of jew’s mallow sold. The relative net margin is calculated as follows in the equation (5) and (6):

The analysis of the net margins was done in two ways: first of all, a comparison of the relative net margins of the actors at the level of each marketing system was done using Student’s t-test.

H0: The relative average net margins of actors in both systems equal two by two.

Secondly,    the     net  margins   of   actors   in   lowlands marketing system were compared two by two.

H0: the relative average net margins of the different actors of SCBF equal two by two.

Equity analysis

The equity of margins sharing by actors is an important performance indicator of a marketing system. The Gini coefficient and the Lorenz curve were used to analyze the distribution of the margins among actors of the most profitable marketing system which is the marketing system of lowland jew’s mallow. The Gini coefficient (or index), a measure of the inequality associated with the Lorenz curve were calculated as indicated in equation (7):

The Gini coefficient varies from 0 to 1. In case of perfect equality, it equals to 0 and in case of total inequality, it equals 1. Therefore, when this coefficient increases from 0 to 1, it will show the distribution of rising inequality.

According to Dillion and Hardaker (1993), Gini coefficient greater than 0.35 indicates that there is inequality distribution. According to Meron (2015), Gini-coefficients are aggregate inequality measures, and can vary anywhere from zero (perfect equality) to one (perfect inequality). In actual fact, the Gini-Coefficient with highly unequal distributions typically lies between 0.50 and 0.70, while with relatively equitable distributions it is on the order of 0.20 to 0.35. However, although Gini-coefficients provide useful information based on Lorenz curve shapes, a problem arises when Lorenz curves cross. It is problematic whether we can in this special case claim that a higher coefficient means a more unequal distribution, so more careful analysis is required (Todaro, 1998). The other problem associated with Gini-coefficients is that it favors equality of market shares without regard to the number of equalized firms. In other words, the coefficient equals zero for two firms with 50% market shares, for three firms with 33.33% market shares each, and so on (Meron, 2015).

A comparison of the margins, using Student’s t-test, among the categories of actors was done in order to better support the results of the Gini Coefficient and the Lorenz curve. 

 

 

 

 

 

 

                                                   


 RESULTS AND DISCUSSIONS

Marketing systems of jew’s mallow 
 
In Agbédranfo, jew’s mallow was produced throughout the year in two (2) distinct production zones. From mid-March (normal cropping season: rainy season) while it was produced in the uplands with three (3) production cycles per year. From mid-November to mid-March (off cropping season), it was produced in the lowland with two (2) production cycles per year. The differentiation of the production zones related to the cropping periods led to the identification of two (2) marketing    periods    of   jew’s    mallow:   normal cropping season (from mid-March to mid- November) and off-season (from mid-November to mid-March) which is the period of shortage.
 
Taking into account the selling periods, the two identified marketing systems are: the marketing system of lowland jew’s mallow and the one of upland jew’s mallow. The different marketing systems are different in their structure. During the shortage, producers can sell directly to retailers or to consumers while in the normal cropping season, they sell mainly to wholesalers. 
 
The socio-demographic data of actors is presented in Table 2. Results showed that the marketing of jew’s mallow is a women’s business (97%). The oldest actor (51 years) and  the  most experimented ones (29 years) were wholesalers. Wholesalers had a seed capital three to four times higher than that of women retailers (Table 2). All wholesalers were widows (Table 2). Generally, most of the actors were illiterate. Large proportions were married and spoke Adja language (Table 2).   
Three (3) categories of actors were identified: producers, retailers and wholesalers. The implication of women in jew’s mallow marketing tallies with the results obtained by Maundu et al. (1999), Vihotogbé (2001), Adjatin (2006), Assogba Komlan (2010) and Levasseur et al. (2007). The limited implication of men (3%) can be explained by the concepts of horizontal and vertical specialization of African towns’ socioeconomics. While the first concept is segregation by gender based on the nature of the activities, the second is an asymmetric sexualcharacterization based on the profitability and the scale of activities (Faure and Labazee, 2002).The appreciable number of widows especially at the level of the wholesalers tallies the requirements of wholesaler. In fact, wholesalers need to often travel exploring production zones. Therefore, they are often absent from home. The presence of a husband could be a constraint to the necessary freedom of action in the performance of her functions.
 
 
 

Depending on the distribution strategies that the different actors of jew’s mallow marketing adopt, three (3) distribution channels of jew’s mallow existed irrespective of the marketing system. These channels were fragmented into sub-channels (Figure 2).

Gross and net margins of the different actors

The Student’s t-tests showed that at the threshold of 5%, the relative average net margins of the actors of the two systems were significantly different two by two (Table 3). The relative net margin in lowland marketing system was higher than the one obtained in the upland marketing system no matter the actors. Moreover, these margins were different from an actor to another no matter the marketing system (Table 3).

Accordingly, marketing of jew’s mallow is more profitable for the lowland marketing system than the upland one. This result tallies with Singbo and Levasseur (2006) who showed that jew’s mallow production is clearly more profitable in the lowlands. Also, Savi (2009) showed that jew’s mallow production is globally profitable in the valley of Mono. These results tally with the present study. In addition, the gross margin per square meter, that is, FCFA 206 obtained in this study is higher than the one (FCFA 120 to 177) obtained in the lowlands in Cotonou by Sodjinou and Komlan (2010).

The difference of margin between both marketing systems depends on many factors. During the period of abundance, that is, in upland jew’s mallow marketing system, the jew’s mallow market of Dogbo, like in any other location, is saturated because the rainy season favours production and supply is higher than demand. Then following the demand theory, prices decreases (Ceteris paribus).  This explains the limited power of women producers from Agbédranfo in the price determination, hence the negative margins.

On the other hand, only developed lowland jew’s mallow production zones (as the study area) produce jew’s mallow during the off-season. Consequently, in that period, competition is low. Thus, during this period, the market of produced jew’s mallow is less saturated, and the price of the basket is very high. Demand becomes higher than supply and unlike the other period of commercialization, producers impose their selling price.

The results tally with the affirmation that gardening crops supply is influenced by the rainfall regime especially for field-grown crops (rainy season), and irrigation practice in some regions. The use of lowland, which is dependent of the rainfall regime, also influences this supply (Agossou et al., 2001).

Analysis of actors’ margin distribution

The margin is the instrument to measure the performance of the activities of commercial actors that gives us a clear picture of their profit distribution from the producer to the retailer. Thus, the Gini index (G) was calculated by taking into account the net margins of the actors in lowland jew’s mallow marketing system. The previous results showed that lowland is more profitable. We will therefore consider lowland marketing system in the analysis of market concentration. The average value of G was: G = 0.34109 (0 <0.34109 < 1). In addition, Gini coefficient is less than 0.35 therefore there is an equal distribution of net margins among the actors.

These results show that there is a low concentration of the marketers. It means that actors of the market have mutual influence in themselves. Since the wholesalers and retailers are not many, they could have influence on the price of the market. And then, they could also be the price setters, which explains their higher net market margins compare to producers’.

This result was illustrated by the Lorenz curve (Figure 3). It showed the distribution of the net margins of the different actors of the marketing. The points of this curve have started gradually to be separated from point A with the coordinates (55.80). Therefore, 80% of the actors had a net margin of 55% and the remained 20% of the cumulated number of actors had a cumulated net margin of 45%. This cumulated net margin corresponded to the net margins of the  majority  of  the  women  retailers  and wholesalers. This result tallies with the one obtained comparing the net margins of these two groups of actors in the marketing system of lowland. There was no significant difference (p > 0.05) between the net margins of the retailers and the wholesalers (Table 3).

This result confirms the results of Kelechi et al. (2013) who found that although the Gini coefficient is 0.49, there were no significant differences between net margins of retailers and wholesalers of okra in South-Eastern Nigeria. Also this result confirms also the findings of Mani (2014) in Katsina State, Nigeria for date palm marketing. Mani (2014) found a Gini coefficient of 0.47 among wholesalers, showing a purely competitive market pointed towards a low level of seller concentration in wholesalers.The Gini index and the Lorenz curve showed an even distribution of the net margins among the actors in the lowland marketing system. Women retailers and wholesalers had the highest profit to the detriment of women producers. The assertion according to which small producers, although they made the major job in agricultural products supply, have very low revenues because of the nature of the inputs used and mainly their living conditions (Nouhoheflin, 2001) tallies with the results of the present study.

The highest net margins are recorded with retailers and wholesalers (Figure 4). This result does not tally with the affirmation that retailers suffer prices imposed by wholesalers without taking into account the supply and demand conditions (Lutz et al., 2006). This result therefore tallies with Lutz et al. (2006) who  stipulate  that retailers do not allow wholesalers to behave like “price makers” in the sense of the “Stackelberg leadership”.

The investments of producers were higher than those of retailers and wholesalers. Moreover, the margins of producers were lower than those of retailers and wholesalers. Margins of actors were not proportional to the invested costs. So there was no equity and the distribution of margins among actors is therefore uneven. Producers are price takers due to the jew’s mallow is very perishable, and they do not have appropriate storage facilities, they are oblige to sell it at a lower price. Also producers, are mainly women (97%), and they receive influence of their husbands and they need cash to take care of their children. These sociologic factors influence their bargaining power. These farmers should be organized into cooperative, which could help to build storage facilities and then contribute to increase their bargaining power.

 

 

 

 
 
 
 
 


 CONCLUSION

The Couffo department is identified as one of the major jew’s mallow producers in Benin. In fact, enjoying the presence of about thirty lowlands and about ten artesian wells, some villages of this department produce jew’s mallow throughout the year. This is the case of the village of Agbédranfo where jew’s mallow producers grow it during the rainy season in the uplands and during the dry season in the lowlands. Jew’s mallow produced is sold throughout the year.

Thus, depending on the production areas of jew’s mallow and the selling strategy, the marketing system of upland jew’s mallow and the one of the lowland jew’s mallow are the two marketing systems in Agbédranfo. Besides the market of Dogbo, jew’s mallow is sold on the farms, in the houses and in the markets of Lokossa and Azovè. It is sold by three groups of actors – women producers, retailers and wholesalers –, jew’s mallow transits through three channels before reaching the consumers.  The selling price fluctuates throughout the year. Cheap during the period of abundance (rainy season), jew’s mallow produced in Agbédranfo is expensive during the dry season. During the period of abundance, only women traders are able to make a positive margin even if it is very small. On the contrary, during the period of shortage (dry season), the profitability of jew’s mallow marketing is effective at the level of all actors. There is an uneven distribution of margins between actors. Retailers, make the highest profits that are 2 to 3 times higher than those of the producers.

The oligopsony during the abundance period, the oligopoly during the shortage period and the price fluctuation due to an unequal demand and supply thus translate the inefficiency of jew’s mallow exchanges. This situation backs up the assertion  according  to  which  the marketing of agricultural products in Africa is subject to many constraints that are, among other, market distortions and imperfections. A better mastery of the marketing techniques of actors could reduce the existing inequality.


 CONFLICT OF INTERESTS

The authors have not declared any conflict of interests.


 ACKNOWLEDGEMENT

The authors greatly appreciate the financial support from AfricaRice (Africa Rice Center) to this study through the Phase 2 of the Project “Realizing the agricultural potential of inland valley lowlands in sub-Saharan Africa while maintaining their environmental services" (RAP2). They are particularly indebted to the journal’s anonymous reviewers who provided vey insightful comments and suggestions. The authors remain solely responsible for any error.



 REFERENCES

Adégbidi A, Dedehouanou H, Kpenavoun S, Lutz C (2003). Dix ans de libéralisation du marché de maïs au Bénin. CDS Research Report No. 20 ISSN 1385-9218, 105p. Available at: 

View

 

Adjatin A (2006). Contribution à l'étude de la biodiversité des légumes-feuilles traditionnels consommés dans le département de l'Atacora (Bénin). Mémoire de DEA, Université de Lomé, Togo. 55p.

 
 

Agossou G, Ahouansou T, Aly D, Assogba-Komlan F (2001). Etude sur la promotion de la filière des cultures maraîchères au Bénin. Rapport principal, MAEP. Bénin. 102p.

 
 

Assogba KF (2010). The production and commercialization of traditional vegetables. In Achigan E, Pasquini M, Assogba Komlan F, Ndanikou S, Dansi A, Ambrose-Oji B (eds). Traditional vegetables in Benin : diversity, distribution, ecology, agronomy, utilization. Imprimerie LSSEE/ INRAB/Bénin. pp. 80-85.

 
 

Bain JS (1951). Relation of profit rate to industry concentration: American manufacturing, 1936-1940. Quaterly J. Econ. 65(3):293-324.
Crossref

 
 

Bain JS (1968). Industrial organization. 2nd Edition. John Wiley and Sons, New York. 

 
 

Bergmann DR (1960). Tour d'horizon sur les problèmes de commercialisation des produits agricoles. Économie rurale. N°44 Commercialisation des produits agricoles. pp. 3-9.
Crossref

 
 

Clodius RL, Muêller WF (1961). Market Structure analysis, an orientation for research in agricultural. 
Crossref

 
 

Demont M, Houedjoklounon A, Hounhouigan J, Mahyao A, Orkwor G, Stessens J, Tollens E, Toure M (2003). Etude comparative des systèmes de commercialisation d'igname en Côte-d'ivoire, au Benin et au Nigéria. Working Paper, n° 79, Département d'Economie Agricole et de l'Environnement, Katholieke Universiteit Leuven.

 
 

Dillion JK, Hardarker JB (1993). Farm Management Research for Small Farmers' Development, Rome, Food and Agriculture Organization. pp. 23-27.

 
 

FAFA, Facilité d'Appui aux Filières Agricoles (2009). Les premiers pas de FAFA: Faciliter la vente du crincrin. Available at: 

View

 
 

Faure YA, Labazee P (2002). Socio-Economie des Villes Africaines : Bobo et Korogho dans les Défis de la Décentralisation, IRD, Editions Karthala, Paris. Available at: 

View

 
 

GTZ : Gesellschaft für Technishe Zusammenarbeit (2007). Manuel de Value Links: La Méthodologie de la Promotion de la chaîne de Valeur Ajoutée. Symbole de cartographie de la chaîne dans les séminaires et documents. First edition. Available at: 

View

 
 

Guidi SMG (2007). Analyse socio-économique de la consommation des légumes à Cotonou: contraintes, attitudes et opportunités. Thèse d'Ingénieur Agronome, Université d'Abomey-Calavi, Benin. 73p. Available at: 

View

 
 

INSAE : Institut National de la Statistique et de l'Analyse Economique (2003). Troisième recensement général de la population et de l'habitation (RGPH3), Résultats Définitifs. INSAE, Direction des études démographiques, Cotonou. 23p. Available at: 

View

 
 

INSAE (2008).Tableau de bord social : Profils socio-économiques et indicateurs de développement, Cotonou, Décembre 2008. p145 avec annexes. Available at: 

View.

 
 

Kelechi AI, Jackson N, Ifeyinwa AA, Ajuruchukwu O (2013). Market Structure, Conduct, Channel and Margin of Dry Season Okra Vegetable in South-Eastern Nigeria. 2013 International Conference on Food and Agricultural Sciences IPCBEE vol.55 (2013) © (2013) IACSIT Press, Singapore
Crossref

 
 

Levasseur V, Pasquini MW, Kouame C, Temple L (2007). A review of urban and peri urban vegetable production in West Africa. Acta Horticulturae 762:245-252.
Crossref

 
 

Lutz C, Erno KW, Tilburgb A (2006). Maize Market Liberalisation in Benin: A Case of Hysteresis. J. Afr. Econ. 16(1):102-133.
Crossref

 
 

Lutz C (1994). The Functioning of the Maize Market in Benin: Spatial and Temporal Arbitrage on the Market of a Staple Food Crop. University of Amsterdam, Dept. of Regional Economics. 

 
 

MANI JR (2014). Structure, Conduct And Performance Of Date Palm marketing In Katsina State, Nigeria, (Online) Thesis of Master, Department Of Agricultural Economics And Rural Sociology, Faculty Of Agriculture, Ahmadu Bello University, Zaria, Nigeria. 83p. Available at: 

View

 
 

Mastaki NJL (2006). Le rôle des goulots d`étranglement de la commercialisation dans l`adoption des innovations agricoles chez les producteurs vivriers du Sud-Kivu (Est de la R.D.Congo). Dissertation originale présentée en vue de l'obtention du grade de docteur en sciences agronomiques et ingénierie biologique, Filière Economie et Développement Rural., Faculté universitaire des sciences agronomiques de Gembloux, Communauté française de Belgique,

 
 

Maundu PM, Njiro EI, Chweya JA, Imungi JK, Seme EN (1999). The biodiversity of traditional leafy vegetable in Kenya. In Chewya J. A. and P. B. Eyzaguirre eds. Biodiversity of traditional leafy vegetables, pp. 51-84.

 
 

Meron Y (2015). Performance and challenges of vegetable market: the case of Kombolcha District, East Hararghe Zone, Oromia National Regional State, Ethiopia, (Online) Thesis of Master, Haramaya University, 107p.

 
 

Ninglepong GT (2004). Etude socioéconomique du système de commercialisation des amandes de mangues sauvages (irvingia spp) dans l'arrondissement de Ngoulemakong (Sud cameroun). Thèse d'Ingénieur Agronome Université de Dschang, Cameroun.

 
 

Nouhoheflin T (2001). Impact socio-économique de l'adoption des nouvelles technologies du niébé sur la réduction de la pauvreté: Cas des départements des Collines et du Couffo. Thèse d'Ingénieur Agronome, FSA, UAC, Bénin. 110p.

 
 

Olagunju F, Babatunde R, Salimonu K (2012). Market Structure, Conduct and Performance of Gari processing Industry in South Western Nigeria. Eur. J. Bus. Manage. 4(2).

 
 

Padonou SCJ (2008). Analyse comparée du revenu et de sa distribution entre les producteurs de tomate utilisant les bio-pesticide et les pesticides chimiques en zone péri urbaines du Sud-Bénin. Thèse d'ingénieur d'agronome, Université de Parakou. 151p. Available at: 

View

 
 

Peltzman S (1976). Toward a More General Theory of Regulation. J. Law Econ. 19(2):211-40.
Crossref

 
 

Pomeroy S, Trinidad AC (1998). Organisation sectorielle et analyse de marché : La commercialisation du poisson. In Scott, G. et Griffon, D. (éds). Prix, Produits et Acteurs. Méthodes pour analyser la commercialisation agricole dans les pays en développement. Editions KARTHALA, CIRAD et CIP, France. pp 255-280.

 
 

RAP: Réalisation du potentiel des zones de Bas-fonds (2010). Promotion des Chaînes de Valeur à base de Riz et de cultures Maraîchères dans les Bas-fonds aux Sud Bénin et Mali: Perceptions Paysannes sur les Contraintes et Opportunités et analyse de la rentabilité financière des systèmes de cultures.eds Adetonah S., O. Coulibaly, E. Sessou, P. Adegbola, U. Dembele, S. Adekambi, Padonou S, Huat J. Rapport final, Composante 4. 33p.

 
 

Santara T (2009). Rentabilité des systèmes de cultures de riz (Oryza spp) et de crincrin (Corchorus olitorius) dans les bas-fonds au sud-Benin : cas des departements du mono et du couffo, mémoire de maîtrise es-Sciences Economiques, FASEG/UAC, Bénin. 84p. Available at: 

View

 
 

Savi A (2009). Analyse de la rentabilité financière et de l'efficacité économique de la production du crincrin (Corchorus olitorius) dans la vallée du Mono. Mémoire pour l'obtention du diplôme d'études Approfondies, FSA/UAC. 93p. Available at: 

View.

 
 

Singbo A, Levasseur V (2006). Analyse socio-économique de la contribution des cultures maraîchères à la valorisation des bas-fonds du centre du Bénin. Document de travail N°1, Institut National des Recherches Agricoles du Bénin (INRAB), The World Vegetable Center (AVRDC), le Centre de Recherches Agricoles - Agonkanmey (CRA-A), le Programme Analyse de la Politique Agricole (PAPA), 103p. Available at: 

View

 
 

Singbo GA, Nouhoheflin T, Idrissou L (2004). Etude des perceptions sur les ravageurs des légumes dans les zones urbaines et périurbaines du sud Bénin. Projet Légumes de qualité, Rapport d'activités, IITA-INRAB-OBEPAB, 21p. Available at: 

View.

 
 

Sodjinou E, Assogba KF (2007). Besoins en financement et définition de stratégies de mise en place de crédits au profit des agriculteurs de Cotonou. Etudes IAGU/ Projet IAGU 3PFP, 23p. Available at: 

View.

 
 

Tirole J (1988). The Theory of Industrial Organization. MIT Press, 1988. Available at: 

View.

 
 

Todaro M (1998). Economics Development. 6th edition New York. McGraw-Hill,Inc. New York, USA. Available at: 

View.

 
 

Tollens E (1997). Cadre Conceptuel Concernant l'Analyse de la Performance Economique des Marchés. Programme FAO-Approvisionnement et Distribution Alimentaire des Villes, FAO, 1997. Available at: 

View.

 
 

Vihotogbé R (2001). Diversité biologique et potentialités socioéconomiques des ressources alimentaires forestières végétales RAFVs (Produits Forestiers non ligneux : PFNLs) de la forêt de POBE et de ses zones connexes. Pour l'obtention du diplômed'Ingénieur Agronome : Cotonou/ FSA/UAC. 102p.

 

 




          */?>